Measuririg the Effects of Sales Below Cost Laws in Retail Gasoline Markets by Rod Wesley Anderson A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Applied Economics MONTANA STATE UNIVERSITY-BOZEMAN Bozeman, Montana December 1995 11 APPROVAL of a thesis submitted by Rod Wesley Anderson This thesis has been read by each member of the thesis committee and has been found to be satisfactory regarding content, English usage, format, citations, bibliographic style, and consistency, and is ready for submission to the College of Graduate Studies. Ronald N. Johnson I), /t-( /9 5 I I Date Approved for the Department of Agricultural Economics and Economics Douglas Young l2_- ~-1 ~ (Signature) Date Approved for the College of Graduate Studies Robert L. Brown (Signature) Date lll STATEMENT OF PERMISSION TO USE In presenting this thesis in partial fulfillment of the requirements for a master's degree at Montana State University-Bozeman, I agree that the Library shall make it available to borrowers under rules of the Library. If I have indicated my intention to copyright this thesis by including a copyright notice page, copying is allowable only for scholarly purposes, consistent with "fair use" as prescribed in the U.S. Copyright Law. Requests for permission for extended quotation from or reproduction of this thesis in whole or in parts may be granted only by the copyright holder. Date _ ___;r-=c..=-r\ _..4_,.[ ....... 7 ..... S: _______ _ iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Dr. Ronald Johnson has contributed an immeasurable amount of time and effort towards this thesis. His attention to detail and ability to discern the relevant problems and questions have been motivational from its beginning. I am grateful for his guidance and patience, which have allowed me to learn throughout the stages of this project. The contributions of Dr. David Buschena and Dr. Thomas Stratmann were also essential to the completion of this thesis. Their efforts and the time they have given are gratefully acknowledged. Finally, I would like to thank my parents and family, whose support and concern is always present. v TABLE OF CONTENTS Page APPROVAL . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii STATEMENT OF PERMISSION TO USE ................................... iii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iv TABLE OF CONTENTS ................................................. v LIST OF TABLES ..............................•....................... vii LIST OF FIGURES .................................................... viii ABSTRACT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix 1. INTRODUCTION ..................................................... 1 2. PREDATORY PRICING THEORY AND IMPLICATIONS OF SALES BELOW COST LAWS .................................... 4 Sales Below Cost Laws ~d Predatory Pricing ........................... 4 Economics and Predatory Pricing ..................................... 6 Applying the Areeda/Turner Rule to SBC Laws ............... · .......... 21 Alternative Explanations for SBC Laws ............................... 25 Conclusion ................ · ...................................... 26 3. DATA DESCRIPTION AND LEGAL REVIEW ........................... 28 Introduction .................................... · .................. 28 An Overview of the Gasoline Distribution System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 The Components of Gasoline Price .................................... 30 Wholesale Price .......................................... ; ... 31 Taxes ...................................................... 33 Retail Margin . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 5 Variables that Affect the Retail Margin ................................ 36 Sales Below Cost Laws . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 Alabama ... · ................................................. 45 VI TABLE OF CONTENTS --- Continued Colorado ..................................................... 45 Florida ..................................................... 46 Massachusetts ................................................ 4 7 Missouri .................................................... 4 7 · Montana .................................. ; ................. 48 New Jersey .................................................. 49 Tennessee ................................................... 49 Utah .........................................•.............. 50 The Effect of SBC Laws: A Preliminary Analysis ........................ 50 Conclusion ....................................................... 57 4. EMPIRICAL TESTS AND RESULTS ................................... 64 Introduction ................................. : .................... 64 Econometric .Considerations ................. ·. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 Model Specification and Results .•.................................... 65 Measuring the Effect on Retail Margins . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 Measuring Response Differences to Increases in Wholesale Price ... ; ........................................ 71 Conclusion ....................................................... 79 5. CONCLUSION ...................................................... 81 REFERENCES CITED .................................................. 84 APPENDICES· ................................ : ........................ 89 Appendix A--Interpolation of Weekly Quantity Data ..................... 90 Appendix B--Descriptive Statistics .................................... 92 Appendix C--Motor Fuels Taxes by City ............................... 95 Appendix D--Sales Below Cost Laws by' State ........................... 98 Appendix E--Regression Results of Equation 4.1 .......... ; .......... ~ .. 100 vii LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1. Calculation of Gasoline Sales Tax ................................... 36 2. Comparison of Descriptive Statistics ofLaw and Non-LawStates .......... 55 3. The Effect of SBC Laws on Retail Margins ............................ 66 4. The Impact of Active Legal Enforcement .............................. 68 5. The Effect of SBC Laws on Retail Price ............................... 70 6. Estimation of the Lag Structure of Prices with a Lagged Dependent Variable .......... · .................................... 73 7. Test of Asymmetrical Price Responses ................................ 77 8. The Differences in Retail Price Response to Increases in Wholesale Prices ................................... 80 9. Descriptive Statistics of Key Variables ................................ 93 10. Motor Fuels Taxes and Computational Formulas ....................... 96 11. Sales Below Cost Laws by State .................................... 99 12. Full Regression Results of Equation 4.1 ............................. 101 viii LIST OF FIGURES Figures Page 1. The Cost Functions of a Typical Finn ................................ 12 2. Price/Quantity Combinations Under the Average Variable Cost Rule ........ 17 3. The Gasoline Distribution System .................................... 30 4. Supply and Demand Illustration of Quantity Purged of Price Effects ........ 42 5. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups in Billings, MT .................. 59 6. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups in Bozeman; MT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 7. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups in Great Falls, MT .......... : . . . . . 61 8. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups in Helena, MT ................... 62 9. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups in Missoula, MT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 10. Time Path for the Cumulative Adjustment of Retail Prices to Wholesale Price Changes .............. · ................... · .... 77 IX ABSTRACT The retail gasoline market in some states is regulated by laws that prohibit the sale of gasoline at prices below the retailer's cost. The stated purpose of these laws is to .offer protection from predatory pricing, a practice whereby one ftrm seeks to eliminate its competition through loss inducing prices. However, the assumption that predatory pricing is occurring in the retail gasoline business is questionable. If predatory pricing is not occurring, the laws may instead protect less efficient firms by establishing a price floor that results in higher prices for consumers. To test this hypothesis, retail margins in states with and without such laws are examined. The results suggest that retail margins tend to be slightly higher in states where sales below cost laws are effective. These results are not consistent with the idea that predatory pricing is a frequently occurring phenomenon in the retail gasoline sector. 1 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION Legislation that has the intent of protecting consumers is often predicated on the fear of market power and monopoly prices. Since predatory pricing may ultimately lead to higher prices, it is one of the strategies that laws supposedly guard against. In the United States, this concern dates to the conception of antitrust laws, most notably the Sherman Act (U.S.C., title 15, sec. 1-7) of 1890.1 A current example is found at the state level where laws in 11 states explicitly prohibit the sale of gasoline at prices below cost. It is argued that absent these laws, firms would temporarily lower prices with the intent of eliminating competition. The ultimate objective is monopoly profits after the victims have. departed the market. If predatory pricing is occurring in the retail gasoline business, such laws, if effective, could protect competition and consumers. But if the structure of the industry is not conducive to predatory pricing, the laws could instead lead to inefficiency by restricting competition and decreasing social welfare. In this case, it is likely that the laws are the result of special interest groups, motivated by a concern for their own well- being. 1Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox, (New York, NY: Basic Books, Inc., 1978), 19. 2 These laws are referred to as Sales Below Cost (SBC) laws and the objective of this thesis is to measure the effects of gasoline specific SBC laws on prices paid by consumers. Chapter 2 of this thesis provides an understanding of the relationship between predatory pricing and SBC laws. The analysis presented offers an indication of the likelihood of predatory behavior in the retail gasoline business. By definition, predatory pricing requires a level of prices that are below some measure of cost. It is therefore necessary for SBC laws to defme this level in a measurable way. But if such a definition is restrictive in terms of eliminating the low prices of more efficient firms, retail margins could be higher. 2 In providing a definition, we appeal to economic theory and utilize a rule developed by Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner.3 By comparing Areeda and Turner's rule with the SBC laws' defmition of predatory pricing, a sense of whether these laws are pro or anti consumer is provided. Following this analysis, it is argued that these laws are unlikely to enhance competition. Instead, they create a binding price floor so that retail margins will be higher in states with gasoline specific SBC laws. It should be emphasized that this hypothesis is conditional on the premise that SBC laws do in fact constrain behavior. Thus, in addition to the above, it is hypothesized that if the laws generally constrain pricing behavior retail prices in states with SBC laws will respond more quickly to increases in wholesale prices. 2The reason for using the retail margin is explained in Chapter 3. 3Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, "Predatory Pricing and Related Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act," Harvard Law Review 88:697-733 (1975). 3 The data to empirically test the hypothesis is described in Chapter 3. In addition, . . evidence of the laws' effects are obtained by examining related legal cases. Further evidence is sought by comparing the descriptive statistics of states with and without SBC laws. A graphical analysis for Montana is also utilized. Given this preliminary examination, Chapter 4 offers empirical tests of the effects of the SBC laws. Models are developed to test the hypothesis and their results are presented. Conclusions are also drawn concerning predatory pricing in the retail gasoline business. Chapter 5 summarizes the connection between the theory of predatory pricing, implications of SBC laws, and the results of the empirical tests. The results do not support the notion that SBC laws protect consumers. 4 CHAPTER2 'PREDATORY PRICING THEORY AND IMPLICATIONS OF SALES BELOW COST LAWS Sales Below Cost Laws and Predatory Pricing Proponents of Sales Below Cost (SBC) laws have often argued that these laws are necessary because of a perceived threat of predatory pricing. State legislators indicate concern over a decrease in competition due to a decrease in the number of independent gasoline retailers.1 It is argued that oil companies, refiners, and other petroleum marketers have the capability and willingness to set their prices below cost for the purpose of eliminating their competition. These predatory pricing practices are generally alleged to follow a particular pattern. First, the retail price of a gallon of gasoline is set below a level that allows an individual retail outlet to recoup the costs incurred in selling a gallon of gasoline. Wholesale gasoline prices and taxes constitute the majority of these costs, but the additional costs of doing business, such as labor, are included. Second, marketers with multiple retail locations use profits from one location to subsidize below cost prices at 1See, Montana. Montana Retail Motor Fuel Marketing Act, Code. Annotated 30- 14-802, and Alabama. Motor Fuel Marketing Act, Statutes. Annotated 8-22-2. 5 another retail location, or individual retail outlets use profits from non-motor fuels products to subsidize prices on motor fuels. The sale of cigarettes, for example, may be used to subsidize the price of motor fuels. Third, vertically integrated oil companies use profits from upstream operations to subsidize motor fuels prices at their retail stations. For example, Exxon would use profits from its refinery operations to subsidize prices at Exxon owned stations. These alleged practices describe a situation in which a company is willin~ to incur additional costs for a period of time so that its competitors can be eliminated. In the short run, prices are lowered below costs and are subsidized by other products, outlets, or the wealth of the predator. The intended victim must follow the lower prices, thus incurring losses. The predator likewise incurs losses during this period, but is capable of maintainirig these losses for a longer period of time than the victim. Eventually, the victim is unable to endure the costs of the predatory campaign and is driven out of business. In a simple market with only two competitors and no entry into the market, the predator supposedly has sufficient mar~et power to capture monopoly profits. The losses incurred during the predatory campaign are presumably recaptured by higher monopoly prices in the post predation period. The assumption that such predatory practices are occurring should be prefaced with several important questions.. First, is it rational for a firm to engage in a predatory campaign, and if so, under what conditions? Second, how can it be determined if the pricing policies of a particular company imply predatory intent? Answers to these questions require a measure of cost and a definition of when prices below that measure of 6 cost are predatory. The SBC laws relating to motor fuels products do not deal explicitly with the first ofthese questions. However, since the underlying assumption is· that predatory practices occur frequently enough to warrant legislative action, it could be assumed that the general belief is that predatory behavior is a rational strategy and that the conditions necessary for this practice to be successful· are present. The majority of the laws do, however, define cost and a make a price below this level predatory. Economics and Predatory Pricing Economic theory offers guidance for analyzing the issue of predatory pricing. A starting point is to ask the question - what are the conditions under which predatory pricing is likely to occur? Several necessary· conditions are generally accepted. First, the predator firm must have an advantage over the intended victim. If both firms are identical, in terms of their cost functions, the predator will incur greater losses during the period of predation than the victim. As the predator decreases price, the victim must follow or risk losing business. When this happens, however, a price taking firm will also decrease the quantity it is willing to sell. Since the quantity demanded at the lower price is greater and the victim is selling a lower quantity, the predator must increase sales.2 Thus, the predator's losses will be greater than those of the victim. If competing firms realize this, the threat of predatory pricing is not credible. Moreover, the predator 21f the price elasticity within the industry is relatively low in the short run this effect may be weak. 7 must realize this as well. Therefore, when the firms involved are identical, the victim would be better off than the predator during and after the predatory campaign, making it highly unlikely that predatory behavior would occur. On the other hand, if the predator has a cost advantage over a competitor, she can conceivably set a pric~ that results in losses during the period of predation that are less than those of the victim. If the victim ?annot incur losses for as long as the predator, predation may be successful. The threat of predatory pricing then becomes credible, and may be a rational, wealth maximizing strategy. The cost advantage does not, however, guarantee that the victim of a predatory campaign will exit the market. Several factors may affect this decision. Most notably, predatory pricing is illegal under U.S. antitrust law.3 Set;:tion 2 of the Sherman Act (U.S.C., title 15, sec. 1-7) prohibits actions to monopolize a market. The Robinson- Patman Act (U.S.C., title 15, sec. 13), also deals with sales at low prices for the intent of eliminating competition. Since firms found guilty of predatory behavior may be subject to treble damages in private suit, the antitrust statutes can act as a deterrent to predatory pricing. Second, the acquisition of outside financing is generally available. If the victim believed that the predatory prices could not be maintained for a long period of time, it may be in her best interest to obtain outside financing until prices returned to their normal level. Finally, the argument can be made that the victim may maintain a presence 3The gasoline SBC laws are industry specific laws that go beyond the Sherman Act (U.S. C., title 15, sec. 1-7) and Robinson-Patman Act (U.S.C., title 15, sec. 13) to protect independent gasoline dealers. 8 because she realizes the lower prices as predatory and not a change in the market or the level of competition. McGee argues that in such a case, a victim of predatory pricing would certainly want to maintain her presence since prices will, at worst, revert back to their previous levels.4 Besides the predator having a cost advantage, the second condition that must be met is that the future expected benefits of predation must outweigh the. costs. Predatory pricing strategies are costly, both to the predator and the victim. It would seem plausible, therefore, to expect that a firm considering a predatory pricing strategy would not do so if the costs were greater than the expected gain. The question then becomes - what are these costs and is their magnitude offset by the future gains? The higher these costs appear to be, the less likely is predatory behavior. The magnitude of the costs will largely depend on the structure of the industry and the length of the predatory period. However, it is possible to .obtain a general perspective of the potential costs facing a would-b~ predator. The most obvious of these costs is incurred through setting a price that yields less than a normal rate of return. It has already been pointed out that these costs will be heightened by the need. on the part of the predator to expand output. Of additional interest, however, is the discounted value of future profits. Correctly analyzing the . situation faced by the predator requires the realization that one dollar received in the · future does not equal one dollar today. In present value terms, and at an interest rate of 4John S. McGee, "Predatory Pricing Revisited," The Journal of Law and Economics 23, no. 2 (Oct. 1980): 296. 9 10 percent, one dollar received one year from now is worth slightly less than 91 cents. If that same dollar is not received until 10 years from the present date, it is worth a little less than 39 cents. As you go further out in time long term predatory practices become increasingly costly and it becomes less likely that future benefits will outweigh the costs of predation. The U.S. Supreme Court's 1986 decision in Matsushita Electric Industrial Co .. Ltd. v.Zenith Radio Corporation et al. 106 S. Ct. 1348 (1986) exemplifies this point. U.S. firms charged that below cost pricing had been used by several Japanese firms with predatory intent. The allegation that this practice had been occurring for 20 years led the Court to rule in favor of Matsushita, stating that it was unlikely that any firm could carry out a predatory strategy over a period of 20 years. 5 Additionally, if the predatory strategy is to be successful, the current competition must not only be driven out of business, but must be kept from re-entering the market at some point in the future. Likewise, other potential competitors must be discouraged from entering if the current competition is eliminated. Realizing that she must somehow limit future entry, the predator must make it difficult, or preferably impossible, for the competitor to return or a new competitor to move in. Even if the predation is successful, the assets of the firm will remain and offer an opportunity for a relatively easy return by the victim or someone else. A solution to this dilemma is for the predator to not only eliminate the competitor, but her assets as well. Unless the value of the assets have for some reason been substantially depreciated, purchasing them is likely to be a costly 5Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd. v Zenith Radio Corporation et al., 106 S.Ct. 1348 (1986). 10 endeavor. Yet, to protect the market power the predator fought for, she must either incur this cost, or somehow make the assets unavailable to others. It follows from the above that if the industry is characterized by barriers to entry, predation may be more attractive. Given substantial barriers to entry, a firm that gains monopoly power will find it easier to protect its position when prices are eventually elevated. The barriers to entry or advantages possessed by the incumbent firm have been classified in three ways by Joe Bain.6 Bain argues that entry can occur easily in the absence of 1) an absolute cost advantage, 2) advantages resulting from product differentiation, and 3) significant economies of large scale. As an industry moves away from a definition of easy entry, an incumbent firm will be characterized by at least one of these three advantages. Each of these advantages implies that a potential entrant will face a relatively higher level of costs than the incumbent currently incurs or has incurred. If this is true, the new entrant will have difficulty if the incumbent firm lowers price even to the level of its current average costs. A similar result may occur if the industry is characterized by high sunk costs. In the presence of a credible predatory threat, a potential entrant may be discouraged from entering the market if the firm faces the future probability of later being driven from the market and thus forfeiting the resources .associated with the sunk costs.7 6Joe S. Bain, Barriers to New Competition (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1956), 12. 7Dennis W. Carlton and Jeffrey M. Perloff, Modem Industrial Organization, 2d ed. (New York: Harper Collins College Publishers, 1994), 387. 11 With these conditions and their caveats in mind, we now consider the relationship between costs and the determination of when a price is predatory. The difficulty of accurately measuring costs and deciding which costs to consider has led to considerable debate over this issue. At the heart of this debate is a concern over destroying legitimate competition through a definition of cost that fails to capture true predatory intent. Motivated by this concern, Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner sought to apply economic analysis to a workable definition of predatory pricing. 8 In doing so they hoped to offer a well reasoned means by which a predatory price could be distinguished from competitive pricing. Their analysis and the resulting rule they propose for the determination of a predatory price is worth examining as it has been used in practice by the courts.9 The Areeda and Turner rule, as it has become known, is based on the relationship between price and the basic measures of cost used in economic theory. Following their lead, a graphical representation of average cost, average variable cost, and marginal cost will be utilized. Figure 1 shows the typical cost functions for a firm. In a perfectly competitive market, each firm takes the price as given, and as such, faces a horizontal demand function at the competitive price. Profit maximization requires that price equals margin~l cost. In the long run, all firms earn zero economic profits so that the competitive price will be dictated by the intersection of marginal cost and the local 8Areeda and Turner, 697-733. 9Carlton and Perl off, 3 89. 12 minimum of the average cost curve. Thus, in a perfectly competitive market, the price will be P c as indicated in Figure 1. The profit maximizing monopolist, on the other. hand, can affe_ct price by producing the quantity at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue. She may then receive a higher price associated with a lower quantity. Prices at these profit maximizing (or loss minimizing) levels should not be considered predatory. Figure I. The Cost Functions of a Typical Firm $/q AC AVC q On the other hand, prices below this level may indicate a voluntary sacrifice of short run profits. The incentives of such a firm may be legitimately called into question, and suggest that predatory pricing has occurred. Areeda and Turner argue the necessity of such a condition, but guard against its sufficiency. It is possible that a frrni could 13 legitimately choose to price below the profit maximizing level. An example given by Areeda and Turner are new firms utilizing low prices to establish themselves in a market. 10 Additional qualifications are therefore necessary. Their analysis initially focuses on prices that are below the profit maximizing · level and either at or above average cost. A price at average cost indicates that a finn's total revenues exactly offset its total costs. As before, the potential exists that firms will be eliminated by such prices, perhaps intentionally. These are less efficient firms than the predator finn and will suffer greater losses. But such a pricing scheme is also consistent with competition. Areeda and Turner argue that even in cases when a price above average cost is exclusionary, it should not be considered a violation of antitrust laws. Prices below average cost indicate that a finn is operating at a loss. Areeda and Turner are careful to point out that this condition does not necessarily imply predatory intent. In this case, a finn can be operating under conditions of loss minimization instead of profit maximization.11 It is, of course, difficult in practice to determine when a finn may be trying to minimize its losses versus attempting to eliminate its rivals. Since such prices may indicate the possibility of predatory intent, and since equally efficient rivals will suffer losses under these conditions, a more precise definition of cost is needed. To accomplish this, Areeda and Turner further delineate prices mto two 10Areeda and Turner, 703. 11The term loss minimization is used in place of profit maximization only because price is below average cost. As such, a finn is operating at a loss and the optimal policy is to minimize losses. Loss minimization and profit maximization both imply that a finn is producing its optimal output. 14 categories. The first includes prices at or above marginal cost. Referring to Figure 1, this would coincide with a 'price/quantity combination such as point A. Equally efficient firms will be operating at a loss due to the pricing practices of the predator. However, as has been previously noted, it is not likely that equally efficient firms will be driven out under this condition. A possible exception is. a firm without compar~ble financial resources. 12 The assumption that outside financing is not available, however, has limited support. Establishing a price floor above marginal cost would therefore encourage inefficiency and adversely affect competition. For this reason, Areeda and Turner argue that prices in this range should not be considered predatory.13 The second case includes prices that are below marginal cost. It is possible that price is below marginal cost and yet above average cost. In this case, neither the firm, nor its equally efficient rival are operating at a loss, even though the social optimum is not being reached. As such, prices above average cost remain non-predatory in terms of anti-trust law. Prices that are below both average cost and marginal cost potentially imply a different story. This corresponds with a price/quantity combination such as point Bin Figure 1. As previously, this scenari L.. ~ 0.15 ~ co . 0 0.1 Cl 0.05 0 ~ i\ I \ I \ ....... v I I'" ~ ,......., ...-1'-' 1--' 1/92 4/92 7/ 32 Billings ) / \ i/ \ \ I .,1\ \ v 1/ \/ \ ..... v \V'~ !'-' f-o -Jjl...j 09 1/ 93 4/ 93 7/93 09 1/ 94 4/ Date -111- MARGIN_..,_ MIN M/U r--. ...... ,_, ~ ...... 94 '7! 94 60 Figure 6. Retail Margms and Mmimum Markups for Bozeman, MT 0.3 0.25 c: 0 0.2 ('Q (!) .... ~ 0.15 e! ·m 0 0.1 0 0.05 0 1\ \ \ r..... ...... / v .....,,._..; ~ 1/~2 4/ ~2 7/ Bozeman lL' !'-"! ~ v !/ \ I \ I.--' ir-"' \ I i\ I if )~ I !\ I \V \I I'-' ...... ~2 10 9. 1/ ~3 4/ ~3 7/ ~3 09 1/~4 Date -a- MARGIN- MIN M/U ~ 1'- \.. "". iH _,..,., """ 4/ ~4 ._,, 94 61 Figure 7. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups for Great Falls, MT Great Falls 0.25 0.2 / 1\ \ c I .Q ~~ VI\ h\ a; (!) 0.15 I L.. \ ~s-t'' I \ i/ )H ~ (]) c. I J \ ~ 0.1 '\ _j 1!! 1\ v ) iH 0 ..... 0 :) ~ '""" 1'-' ~· ' j ,...... ~ ,....... .._I'-. ~ ,_.. ...... 0.05 ,.._., \ 0 1 ...... ,~-~2-t-l-4-l/9-:2+-+7-+/3-l:2f-f-0+9-+,, -+-1/+-93+-+4-i/f-93+-+7-+/9~:31-+0+9~f-1/+-94-l-f4-,t-~4+-+7-l/ ~-f-1·4 Date - MARGIN- MIN M/U 62 Figure 8. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups for Helena, MT 0.25 0.2 c: ..Q -m <.9 0.15 .... (]) c. ~ 0 .!!! .1 0 0 0.05 0 \ 4 IJ 1/~2 / I 1/ ...... ~ 1 ~ ....., ''I 4/32 7/92 Helena ..... 1/ 1\ ~~ I I I \ \ ...., I 1\ ! 1/ f-' ...... J.r- L\. ..... r-.. !'-.... 1/ -,/ \ ...... ' ~ I 'I 09 1/ 33 4/:}3 7/~3 09 1/ Date -111- MARGIN-'~'- MIN M/U I\ \ ...... ~ ~ 1'-' 94 4/ ~4 7/ ~4 63 Figure 9. Retail Margins and Minimum Markups for Missoula, MT 0.35 0.3 § 0.25 m (!) ..... 0.2 Q) c. ~ 0.15 .!Q 0 0 0.1 0.05 0 \ \ 1/~2 / v "~--~ '/ ,..... 4/ 92 7/ ~2 Missoula \ \ 1\ ~v \ \ 1/ 1\ \ ~~ !\ II\ / \ 1 ~~ 1/ I 1/ ~~ \ ..... ~ \ I r-' IJ rr 0/9. 1/ 93 4/ 93 ..,, 93 0/9 1/ ~4 4/ Date ---MARGIN-.- MIN M/U \ )~ '""'! ,_,I-' 94 ..,, ~4 64 CHAPTER4 EMPIRICAL TESTS AND RESULTS Introduction The purpose of this chapter is to empirically test for the effect of the SBC laws. The analysis begins with the econometric specification of the models used in undertaking the various tests. Several models are constructed. The first of these include 92 weekly, time dummy variables to account for a seasonal pattern in the retail margins. The issues of asymmetric response to changes in wholesale prices and the lag structure of prices are also empirically examined. Econometric Considerations The use of pooled data presents several problems. For example, this is time series data and the error terms may be serially correlated. Indeed, diagnostic tests performed on margin data for each city indicated the presence of first order autocorrelation that varies across cities. Additionally, in cross sectional data there is the potential problem of heteroscedastic errors. Application of the Bruesch-Pagan test rejects the hypothesis of homoscedasticity. 2 Estimation of the models therefore requires correction for an error 2T.S. Breusch and A.R. Pagan, "A Simple Test for Heteroscedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation," Econometrica 47 (1979): 1287-1294. term with the following specification; 65 E(e2 \=a2 ir i e =p e +J.t it i i,t-l it with J.ttt-N(O,a!1 ) The estimation procedure uses the method described in Kmenta (1986) to correct for cross-sectional heteroscedasticity and first order autocorrelation with pooled data. 3 Model Specification and Results Measuring the Effect on Retail Margins The model used to test the hypothesis that SBC laws may result in higher retail margins is Margin it= Po +P1Retwageit +P2Prvaltt +P3Popdentt + T-1 P4NSSit+PsLAWtt+ L YuWu+ett • where Margin = the retail margin, Retwage = the retail wage, Prval = the property value, Popden =the population density, t=l NSS = a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 for cities within f?tates that prohibit the sale of self service gasoline and 0 otherwise,4 (4.1) LAW = a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 for cities within states that have a gasoline specific SBC law and 0 otherwise, and Wt =a weekly dummy variable for timet (T=93). 3Jan Kmenta, Elements of Econometrics, 2d ed., (New York: MacMillan Publishing Company, 1986), 618-622. 4New Jersey and Oregon prohibit the sale of self service gasoline. In this sample, Newark and Portland are affected by this law. 66 Table 3 lists the regression results. The coefficient on LAW is positive and significant, indicating that gasoline SBC laws increase retail margins, on average, by approximately .8 cents. With the exception of the retail wage, all other variables have the expected signs and are statistically significant at the 5 percent level or greater. 5 Of additional interest are the substantially higher margins in states that prohibit the sale of self service gasoline. Table 3. The Effect of SBC Laws on the Retail Retwage Prval(,OOO) Popden(,OOO/sq mile) NSS LAW -0.007 0.040 -0.113 5.810 0.841 -0.545 6.053*** -2.148** 5.732*** 1.976** Adjusted R2 = .49 Denotes significance at: *** .= 1%, ** = 5% Number of Observations= 3720 It is a reasonable assumption, however, that the effect on margins is greater if the laws are actively enforced. As was shown in Chapter 3, four of the six recent cases occurred in Alabama. Thus, if active enforcement increases the likelihood that SBC laws have effect, the margins in Alabama should be higher relative to other states with SBC 5See Appendix E for the results of this regression, including the time dummy variables. · 67 laws. A model to test this is Margin 11 =Po +P1Retwage11 +P2Prval11 +P3Popden 11 + T-1 P4NSSu+PsLAWu+P~Lu+ L YuW1,+eu • t=l (4.2) where AL = a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if the city is in Alabama and zero otherwise. 6 All other variables are as previously defined. Table 4 shows the regression results for this equation. The coefficient on the variable AL indicates that margins are 2.22 cents higher in Alabama relative to other states with SBC laws. The variable LAW remains positive, but is not statistically signif1cant. Thus, active enforcement, as in the case of Alabama, appears to be an important factor for SBC laws to lead to higher margins.7 An additional test of the effect on margins can be made if a particular state's SBC law became effective during the time period of the sample. Missouri and Colorado fit this criteria. A simple model to test for higher margins after the effective date of the law for an individual city is Margin, = Po + P1LAW1 +TIME, +E1 where LAW = a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 for the time period after the effective date of the SBC law and is 0 otherwise, and TIME = a time trend variable to account for inflationary effects. 6Birmingham is the only city in Alabama represented in the sample. (4.3) 'Tennessee and Utah have each had one case since 1985, indicating only a slight amount of enforcement. A dummy variable that includes these states in equation 4.2 is not statistically significant, supporting the notion that active enforcement is a primary determinant of the effect on margins. 68 Enforcement Retwage -0.013 -1.036 Prval(,OOO) 0.043 6.423*** Popden(,OOO/sq mile) -0.098 -1.840* NSS 6.106 5.857*** LAW 0.359 0.743 AL 2.220 2.564** Adjusted R2 = .49 Denotes significance at: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, *=10% Number of Observations = 3 720 This model is run for each of three cities represented in Missouri and Colorado. In each case, the coefficient P1 is negative and not statistically significant, indicating that· introduction of the laws did not affect the margin. Equations 4.1 and 4.2, however, do not take into account seasonal demand changes that may vary between cities. To account for this, the quantity variable detailed in Chapter 3 was included. Data was obtained from the Federal Highway Administration's table "Highway Use of Gasoline by States". 8 Since these data are estimates distributed so as to preserve seasonal driving patterns, some error may be involved. Moreover, lags of up to 6 weeks before consumption make these questionable 8Department of Transportation, Table MF-26. The obvious reporting errors in the alternative sources makes their use difficult and authenticity questionable. 69 proxies for current demand. 9 If the observed quantities accurately measure demand, quantity and margin should be positively correlated. Recall the quantity/seasonality variable constructed in the previous chapter. Observed weekly quantities, Q, were interpolated from the source listed above. An instrument, yielding price-effect corrected quantities, Q, was constructed and these variables were then normalized around their mean values. When the price elasticity of demand, T}, is set to zero, the normalized Q is equal to Q. The inclusion of that variable into equation 4.1 yielded a coefficient that was not significantly different from zero, contrary to the hypothesized effect. Experimenting by including the price effect corrected quantity forT}= -.1, increased the coefficient value to 13.35, while forT} = -.2, the coefficient value became 30.77.10 The variable LAW, however, was not affected by the inclusion of either Q or Q. Since the results are highly sensitive to small changes in the price elasticity and there appear to be potentially serious errors in the data, we rely on the weekly time dummies to accommodate the seasonal demand patterns. Another but more complicated model in terms of the error structure, uses the retail price as the dependent variable. In this case, wholesale prices and taxes are included as explanatory variables since these vary over time and across cities. In equation form this IS 9Borenstein and Shepard (1993) included a similar quantity measure in their paper. They also note that current demand may affect margins through peak-load pricing or as a result of increased demand elasticity during peak driving months. 10Both coefficients for Q are statistically significant at the 1 percent level. 70 Retpriceit =Po +P1 Whlpricf?u +P2Taxit +P3Retwage11 +P4Prval11 + (4.4) T-1 PsPopdentt +P6NSStt +P1LAW;;+ L ytwtt +ett ' where Retprice = the retail price, Whlprice = the wholesale price, and Tax= motor fuels taxes. t=l All other variables~ including time dummies, are as previously defined. The regression results are shown below in Table 5. Again, the coefficient on the variable LAW remains positive, but it is not statistically significant. However, we note that the coefficient on the Whlprice variable is only 0.557. This would seem to suggest that wholesale price changes are not fully passed on to the retail level. This issue is addressed in the following section. Table 5. The Effect ofSBC Laws on Retail Price Whlprice Tax Retwage Prval(,OOO) Popden(,OOO/sq mile) NSS LAW Adjusted R.2 = .51 Number of Observations= 3720 0.557 1.073 -0.011 0.050 -0.151 7.852 0.475 20.800*** 22.310*** -0.860 8.488*** -2.815*** 8.551 *** 1.281 Denotes significance at: * * * :::;: 1% · Measuring Response Differences to Changes in Wholesale Price 71 The previous results indicate that retail margins are somewhat affected by the SBC laws. But a binding price floor could also cause retailers to react more quickly to. increases in wholesale prices. This argument assumes that retail prices do not adjust instantaneously to changes in wholesale prices and the results reported in Table 5 seem to affirm this. The effect of SBC laws on adjustment processes can be measured by interacting the LAW variable with current and lagged wholesale prices. Conducting this test, however, requires prior knowledge about the lag structure of retail prices. The analysis of the lag structure began by experimenting with various free form lags on the wholesale price. Equation 4.4 then becomes, n Retprice1, =Po+ L a.1Whlprice1.,_1 +P1Taxu +P2Retwageu +P3Prvalu + j=O T-1 P4Popdenu +P5NSSu +P6LAWu + L y,W1, +eu . t=l (4.5) A consistent pattern emerges as more lagged terms of the wholesale price are added to this equation. The coefficient on the contemporary wholesale price is consistently between .55 and .60, similar to its value in equation 4.4. The second through fourth weeks are characterized by negative adjustments in retail price. Following this, retail prices begin a slow positive adjustment towards a new equilibrium level. Long adjustment processes are often modeled by including a lagged dependent 72 variable as an explanatory variable in equation 4.4. A simple Koyck lag, however, seems inappropriate given the negative adjustment indicated by equation 4.5.11 A model with a lagged dependent variable that does capture the negative adjustment after the first period lS 2 Retprice 11 = a+ .1: PiWhlprice l,t-j +P3Retprice 1,1_1 +P 4 Tax 11 +P 5Retwage 11 + ( 4 .6) j=O T-1 P6Prval11 +P1Popden 11 +PgNSS11 +P9LAW11 + L y 1W 11 +E11 • t=l The results of equation 4.6 are given in Table 6. To test the significance of including the one and two period lagged wholesale prices, an F -test was run on the null hypothesis that P1 = P2 = 0. This hypothesis is rejected, supporting the time path indicated by equations 4.5 and 4.6 (F=20.00). Further evidence that is consistent with this result is given when considering the following issue. It has been argued that retail prices respond more quickly to positive changes in wholesale prices than negative. Starting from an initial equilibrium position, a wholesale price decrease supposedly affords. a retailer the opportunity for short run profits if the current retail price is maintained. However, under competition the higher prices will not persist. Asymmetry has been attributed to the· presence of market power amongst retailers. Shin, however, points to inventory adjustments as one reason for price 11L.M. Koyck, Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis, (Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company, 1954). 73 Table 6. Estimation of the Lag Structure of Prices · with a Variable Whlpricet Whlpricet-I Whlpricet.2 Retpricet-I Taxt Retwaget Prvalt (,000) Popden. (,000/sq mile) NSSt LAWt 0.567 -0.603 0.132 0.887 0.122 0.0006 0.004 -0.014 0.676 0.142 19.890*** -14.490*** 4.582*** 113.600*** 11.260*** 0.356 4.383*** -1.586 4.359*** 2.120** Adjusted R2 = .88 Denotes significance at: *** = 1%, ** = 5% Number of Observations = 3640 asymmetry in competitive markets.12 During periods of tight supply, increases in wholesale price may be passed along especially fast. If there is excess supply, however, firms may purchase for future periods as well, thereby slowing the downward movement of retail prices. Moreover, the discussion of gasoline retail markets presented in Chapter 2 suggests that it is highly competitive, thus bringing into question the arguments that price changes are asymmetric for uncompetitive reasons. Various studies have been done on price asymmetry in the context of the 12David Shi.Il, "Do Product Prices Respond Symmetrically to Changes in Crude Prices," (Washington, D.C.: American Petroleum Institute, Research Study #068, 1992), 4. 74 petroleum products industry. The results vary, depending on the model and data set used. 13 Bacon, for example, uses a non-linear partial adjustment model and fmds only a slight amount of asymmetry .14 In this model, a quadratic term is included to measure the adjustment process. Changes between wholesale and retail prices were modeled as llNRetpr11 =P0(0 + <1>1 Whlprice1,1_1 - NRetpr1,t-1) + (4.9) P1( 1 Whlprice1,t-1 - NRetpr1,1_/ + e11 where aNRetprit is the change in retail prices net of taxes. If P1 = 0, the model reduces to a linear form and no asymmetry is present. Using Bacon's model we find that asymmetry is present, with positive changes occurring more quickly than negative. The size of the coefficient pb however, is extremely small (.007), indicating that the amount of asymmetry is inconsequential. An alternative estimating procedure is presented by Borenstein, Cameron, and Gilbert (BCG).15 They study price asymmetry at various levels of the petroleum products industry with a lag adjustment model that incorporates an error-correction term to account for a long run stable relationship between the two price series. If retail and wholesale prices tend to have a fairly constant long run relationship, the error correction term will 13Ibid., 6-11. 14Robert W. Bacon, "Rockets and Feathers: The Asymmetric Speed of Adjustment of U.K. Retail Gasoline Prices to Cost Changes," Energy Economics 13, no. 3 (June 1991): 211-218. 15Borenstein, Cameron, and Gilbert, (1994). 75 account for this relationship. BCG model this by including in the regression equation an error correction term of the form : Retprice1 t-1 =<1>0 +<1>1 Whlprice1 ,_1 +£1 t-1 ' ' ' (4.10) They then partition the wholesale prices into increasing and decreasing first differences. For our purposes, this can be represented as: AWhlprice1; = Whlprice1, -Whlprice1 t-1' if Whlpricett -Whlprice1 t-1>0, ' ' = zero otherwise AWhlprice1; = Whlpricett-Whlprice1,,_1, if Whlprice 11 -Whlprice1,t-1<0, = zero otherwise (4.11) BCG fmd that the positive and nega~ive adjustment processes are statistically different from each other up to 8 weeks after a change in wholesale price, with positive responses occurring more quickly than negative.16 Following their lead, we include the same error correction term in a slightly different model.17 The model estimated is shown in equation 4.12 and the results are listed in Table 7. n ANRetpr1, =a0 + .E (p;Awhlprice1~-k +P;Awhlprice1~-k) k=O +6/YRetpr1.t-t +61 Whlprice1.t-t +62TIME1, +£11 16lbid., 26. (4.12) 17Their model also includes lagged positive and negative differences of the dependent variable as explanatory variables. Here, the disturbance term is corrected for autocorrelation. 76 The error-correction term insures that retail prices fully adjust to wholesale prices according to their long run relationship.18 Note that dividing 6 1 by 60 yields an estimate of the coefficient b shown in equation4.10. The results, reported in Table 7, yield a 4>1 equal to .8. Although less than unity, this constraint results in plausible time paths of adjustment. The time paths using the results presented in Table 7 are given in Figure 10. The results indicate a large first period response, followed by a negative adjustment and then a gradual ascent to a long run equilibrium. This is consistent with the previous results from equations 4.5 and 4.6. A slight amount of asymmetry is indicated using this model, although in the opposite direction than that which supports the premise of market power.19 An F-test also rejects the hypothesis that the contemporary positive and negative changes are equal (F = 5.94). Another approach to testing for price asymmetries was proposed by Wolfram.20 As with the procedure by Borenstein, Cameron, and Gilbert, this procedure partitions the data by positive and negative first differences such as: 18Excluding the error correction term yields results that do not indicate full adjustment of retail prices to changes in wholesale prices. 19 An F -test of the difference between equation 4.12 and a model that does not split wholesale prices into positive and negative differences is statistically significant. This indicates a statistically significant difference between positive and negative changes. Therefore, some asymmetry is present. 20Rudolf Wolfram, "Positivistic Measures of Aggregate Supply Elasticities: Some · New Approaches - Some Critical Notes," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53 (1971): 356-59. James P. Houk, "An Approach to Specifying and Estimating Nonreversible Functions," American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59 (Aug., 1977): 570-72, proposes a method of partitioning the independent variable with a slightly different specification than that employed by Wolfram. 77 Table 7. Test of Asymmetrical Pnce Responses Dependent Variable = aNRetpr +a Whlpricel +a Whlpricet-1 -a Whlpricel -a Whlpricet-1 Retprice1_1 Whlprice1_1 TIME 0.406 -0.092 0.569 -0.159 -0.099 0.080 -0.003 9.286*** -2.138** 14.940*** -4.038** -14.840*** 10.040***' -1.860* Adjusted R_2 = .18 Denotes significance at: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10% Number of Observations = 3640 · Figure 10. Time Path for the Cumulative Adjustment of Retail Prices to Wholesale Price Changes 0.9 0.8 - 0.7 c:: Q) ~ 0.6 ::l ~ 0.5 ~ 0.4 "5 E 8 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 I II II II !j' 0 Ill I I I I I I I I ~ -~ -II It-- __, ,__ II" - ------ -- f.---" 2 3 4 5 6 Weeks after Wholesale Price Change -'ltl'- Positive Adjustment -a- Negative Adjustment I-- 7 78 AWhlpriceitc.O AWhlprice it:S 0 (4.13) Then, a new vector of prices, WP 'it , is formed for the increasing phase. The initial value of this vector is formed by adding the first A Whlpriceit ~ 0 to the initial value of the vector of observed wholesale prices. Succeeding values of A Whlpriceit ~ 0 are then summed to the previous values of WP'it· A new vector of prices, WP"it, is formed for the decreasing phase in the same manner using values of A Whlpriceit :s;; 0. The vector of lagged whol~sale prices is partitioned following the same procedure. In this case however, the first observation is lost. The initial value of the lagged wholesale prices thus becomes the base value upon which all succeeding positive or negative changes are summed. Applying this procedure for each city yielded mixed results with many of the estimated coefficients being unrealistic. This could be the consequence of using a lagged term that requires the exclusion of the initial observation. The preceding tests indicate only a slight amount of asymmetry and the direction of the asymmetry is sensitive to the model being used. Thus, the results are not consistent with the hypothesis that the retail gasoline bus~ess is non-competitive. Recall that it was argued that retail prices would respond more quickly to positive changes in wholesale price than negative changes and the majority of the adjustment would not occur in the contemporary period. With these issues in mind, we may now proceed with measuring differences in price responsiveness between law and non-law states. To accomplish this, consider equation 4.12. This model is particularly appropriate since the hypothesized effect will occur for price increases. Interacting the 79. LAW dummy variable with the current and lagged positive changes of wholesale price allows a measure of any difference between SBC law states and non-SBC law states. The equation estimated is n I!:JVRetpr11 = a 0 + L [p;.6.whlprice1;_k + p;.6.whlprice1~-k] + k=O n L [(y;.6.Whlprice1;_k*LAW1)+60NRetpr1,t-t + k=O 61 Whlprice1.t-t +62TIME1, +ett , (4.14) for n = 2. The hypothesis is supported if the coefficients on the interaction terms (yk+) are \ positive. The results of this regression are shown in Table 8. None of the yk+ coefficients are significantly different from zero.21 Conclusion The above tests, utilizing the retail margin as the dependent variable, indicate that SBC laws do affect the pricing behavior of firms in the retail gasoline business, at least to some extent. It was initially shown that margins were moderately higher in states with SBC laws. The majority of this effect, however, was attributed to active enforcement of the laws. These results are also consistent with the premise that predatory pricing is not a common occurrence in the retail gasoline business. Regression runs using the retail price as the dependent variable and allowing for a 21These results are not affected if the LAW variable is also interacted with the negative changes. Table 8. The Differences in Retail Price +A Whlpricet +A Whlpricet-1 -A Whlpricet ·A Whlpricet.1 +A Whlpricet * LAW +A Whlpricet.1 * LAW Retpricet_1 Whlpricet_1 TIME 80 0.400 -0.093 0.568 -0.160 -0.047 0.007 -0.099 0.081 -0.003 to Increases in Wholesale Prices 8.646*** -2.027** 14.920*** -4.051 *** 0.453 0.067 -14.830*** 10.040*** -1.829* Adjusted R2 = .18 Observations= 3640 Significant at:***= 10%, **= 5%, * = 1% distributive lag process also revealed a statistically significant positive effect of the SBC laws on price. However, it is also clear that the error structure in those models is especially complex. Introducing a more detailed adjustment model allowed for the testing of additional hypotheses. These results, however, do not indicate that retail prices in states with SBC laws respond more quickly to increases in whol~sale prices, therefore suggesting that SBC laws are not always binding. 81 CHAPTERS CONCLUSION The objective of this thesis was to quantify the effects of Sales Below Cost laws in the retail gasoline business. To accomplish this, implications of the laws were iriferred from economic theory and a workable definition of a predatory price. Based on the conditions of ~ost advantage, expected profits, and entry deterrence, the potential for predatory pricing in the retail gasoline business appears unlikely. In comparison with the Areeda and Turner rule, the SBC laws appear to define cost so as to restrict competition and set a binding price floor. But if the laws are unnecessary and their effect is to restrict, rather than protect, competition, why were they enacted? A plausible answer is that political pressures, initiated by special interest groups, namely independent dealers, have resulted in regulations that protect less efficient firms. This hypothesis would be supported if retail margins in states with SBC laws were higher than states without such laws. Additionally, if the laws are binding, retail gasoline stations in states with SBC laws will increase retail . prices more quickly in response to wholesale price increases. Several preliminary analyses were conducted to obtain a sense of how actively the laws are enforced. Active enforcement would be prima facie evidence that SBC laws are binding. The analysis revealed scant evidence of enforcement, except in the state of 82 Alabama. However, this is merely prima facie evidence and the mere threat of penalties may be sufficient to make a SBC law binding. Thus we began to ·look for direct evidence of a binding price floor. By comparing descriptive statistics, it was revealed that the minimum value of margins were higher in states with SBC laws. And in Montana, retail margins were typically above the minimum markup. These results suggested that the pricing behavior of firms may be affected by these regulations. While suggestive, further defining and quantifying the effect required empirical tests using time series, cross sectional data. The results indicated that margins are affected by the SBC laws, but the majority ofthis effect is the result of active enforcement of the law in Alabama. Also, the speed of retail price adjustment in response to increases in wholesale prices was not affected. Although the effect of these laws may be weak, the results support the premise that the industry is not characterized by predatory pricing. Rather than protecting independent dealers from predatory behavior, SBC laws appear to be directed at protecting these same firms from competition. These results should be understood in the context of several characteristics of the data set. First, the cost data used in the margin equation is aggregate city-wide data and although the data set includes 3720 observations, the variability in these cost measures only occurs acr9ss the 40 cities. Second, the nearly impossible task of obtaining the invoice cost of fuel to a typical retailer could result in overestimated margins. Some correction for this problem was offered by the inclusion of the population density variable to account for expected differences in types of ownership based on demographics. Third, measurement of the varying seasonal effect between cities was made difficult by 83 inadequate data on the quantity of gasoline consumed. A more extensive time series could prove beneficial because seasonal patterns may be identifi~d with more certainty and time series variability could be added to the· explanatory variables. An interesting and additional aspect ofthis study was the analysis of the lag structure of prices and the hypothesis or' asymmetry between positive and negative changes in price. The assumption that the retail gasoline business is relatively competitive imposes several prior expectations about such price behavior. We expect, for example, that retail prices will respond symmetrically to changes in wholesale prices. Since the existing literature arg'!les otherwise, further study in this area is warranted. 1 This would necessitate, however, reliable price data that is preferably measured in time periods that allow reasonable estimates. An additional area of interest relating to the gasoline business is the types of contractual ownership that exist. Although hampered by the accessibility of data, this issue is relevant to recent legislation that, as with Sales Below Cost laws, assumes strategic behavior on the part of large firms. 1For example, Borenstein (1991) argues that price discrimination occurs within the retail ga5oline business based on customers willingness switch between retail stations. 84 REFERENCES CITED 85 References Cited Alabama. Motor Fuel Marketing Act. Statutes, Annotated. 1984. American Petroleum Institute. Policy Analysis Department. "An Overview of Gasoline Prices and Their Determination." Washington D. C.: American Petroleum Institute, 1990. American Petroleum Institute. State Governmental Relations Department. "State Gasoline Excise Tax Rankings- May 4, 1993." Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Institute, 1993. Areeda, Phillip, and Donald F. Turner. "Predatory Pricing and Related Practices Under Section 2 ofthe Sherman Act." Harvard Law Review 88 (1975): 697-733. Bain, Joe S. Barriers to New Competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1956. Barron, John M., Mark A Lowenstein, and John R. Umbeck, "Predatory Pricing: The Case of the Retail Gasoline Market." Contemporary Policy Issues 3 (Spring 1985): 131-39. Borenstein, Severin. "Selling Costs and Switching Costs: Explaining Retail Gasoline Margins~" The Rand Journal ofEconomics 22 (Autumn 1991): 354-69. Borenstein, Severin, A Colin Cameron, and Richard Gilbert. "Do Gasoline Prices Respond Asymmetrically to Crude Oil Price Changes." Program on Workable Energy Regulation, University of California Energy Institute, PWP- 001R, 1994. Borenstein, Severin, and Andrea Shepard. "Dynamic Pricing in Retail Gasoline Markets." National Bureau ofEconornic Research, Research Paper No~ 1269, Sept., 1993. Bork, Robert H. The Antitrust Paradox. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1978. Breusch, T.S., and AR. Pagan. "A Simple Test for Heteroscedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation." Econometrica 47 (1979): 1287- 1294. 86 Burns, Malcolm R. "Predatory Pricing and the Acquisition Cost of Competitors." Journal ofPolitical Economy 94, no. 2 (April1986): 266-296. Carlton, Dennis W., and Jeffrey M. Perloff. Modern Industrial Organization. New York, N.Y.: Harper Collins College Publishers, 1994. Colorado. Unfair Practices Act. Revised Statutes, Annotated. 1993. Dahl, Carol and Thomas Sterner. "Analyzing Gasoline Demand Elasticities: A Survey." . Energy Economics (July 1991): 203:-210. Dennison, Mike. "Restriction on Gasoline Prices Widely Criticized." Great Falls Tribune, 25 Sept. 1995,.2(A). Dougher, Rayola, and Thomas F.Hogarty. "The Impact of State Legislation on the Number ofRetail Gasoline Outlets." Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Institute, Research Study 062, 1991. Easterbrook, Frank H. "Predatory Strategies and Counterstrategies." The University of Chicago Law Review 48, no. 2 (1981): 263- 337. Florida. Motor Fuel Marketing Practices Act. Statutes, Annotated. 1985. Gellerson - Sawides, Evi. "The Effects of State Below Cost Selling Laws on Retail Prices ofMotor Gasoline." Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Instititute, Research Study 043, 1987. · · Hogarty, Thomas F., and Perry M. Lindstrom. "Empirical Examination of Allegations of Below Cost Retail Selling of Gasoline by Refiners." Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Institute, Research Study 038, 1986. Houck, James P. "An Approach to Specifying and Estimating Nonreversible Functions." American Journal of Agricultural Economics (Aug. 1977): 570-72. Kmenta, Jan. Elements of Econometrics: 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan Publishing Company, 1986. Koyck, L.M. Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company, 1954. Massachusetts. Unfair Sales Act for the Retail Sale ofMotor Fuels. General Statutes, Annotated. 1950. 87 McGee, JohnS. "Predatory Pricing Revisited." The Journal ofLaw and Economics 23, no. 2 (Oct. 1980): 289-330. Missouri. Missouri Motor Fuel Marketing Act. Code, Annotated. 1993. Montana. Montana Retail Motor Fuel Marketing Act. Code Annotated. 1991. Motor Fuel Pricing Problems. prepared by Paul E. Verdon, Staff Researcher. Helena, MT: Montana Legislative Council, 1990. New Jersey. Unfair Motor Fuels Practice Act. Statutes, Annotated. 1953. Oil and Gas Journal. (Tulsa, OK) 23 Mar. 1992- 27 Dec. 1993. Scherer, F.M. "Predatory Pricing and the Sherman Act: A Comment." Harvard Law Review 89 (1976): 869-890. Shepard, Andrea. "Contractual Form, Retail Price, and Asset Characteristics in Gasoline Retailing." The Rand Journal ofEconomics 24 (Spring 1994): 58-77. Shin, David. "Do Product Prices Respond Symmetrically to Changes in Crude Prices?" Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Institute, Research Study #068, 1992. Solomon, Caleb. "Independent Gas Stations Cry Foul Over Price Wars." The Wall Street Journal, 1 April 1991, 7(B). Sorenson, Philip E., Rayola S. Dougher, Lisa A. Ho:finan, and Thomas. F. Hogarty. "An Economic Analysis of the Distributor-Dealer Wholesale Gasoline Price Inversion of 1990: The Effects ofDifferent Contractual Relations." Washington D.C.: American Petroleum Institute,-1991. The Road Information Program. 1993 State Highway Funding Methods. Washington, D.C.: The Road Information Program, 1993. Tennessee. Petroleum Trade Practices Act. Code, Annotated. 1977. Tennessee. Unfair Sales Law. Code, Annotated. 1937. U.S. Department of Commerce. Economics and Statistics Administration. County and City Data Book: 1994. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994. 88 ____ . 1992 Census ofRetail Trade. Geographic Area Series. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994. U.S. Department ofEnergy. Energy Information Administration. Petroleum Marketing Monthly. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, Mar. 1992- Dec. 1993. ----·· Petroleum Stipply Annual1993. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994. U.S. Department ofEnergy. Minimum Markup Laws in Gasoline Marketing: An Economic Analysis and a Legal, Economic and Legislative Review. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1985. U.S. Department of Transportation. Federal Highway Administration. Monthly Motor Fuel Reported by States. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, Mar. 1992 - Dec. 1993. ____ . Highway Statistics. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1992, 1993. Utah. Motor Fuel Marketing Act. Code, Annotated. 1981. Williamson, Oliver E. "Predatory Pricing: A Strategic and Welfare Analysis." The Yale Law Journal 87, no. 2 (1977): 284- 340. Wolffram, Rudolf. "Positivistic Measures of Aggregate Supply Elasticities: Some New Approaches- Some Critical Notes." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53 (1971): 356-59. 89 APPENDICES 90 APPENDIX A INTERPOLATION OF WEEKLY QUANTITY DATA 1) Let: 91 Interpolation Method of Weekly Quantity/Seasonality Variable a) ~vol = the monthly total volume for the current month. This value will become the quantity value for the last day of the current month. b) lagmvol = the monthly total volume for the previous month. This value will become the quantity value for the last day of the previous month. 2) Calculate the slope of a line between mvol and lagmvol. slope = (mvol - lagmvol)/no. of days in current month 3) Multiply slope times the number of days corresponding to the date of the price observation. 4) Add result from (3) to lagmvol to get the weekly quantity for that observation. 92 APPENDIXB DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS 93 Table 9. Descriptive Statistics ofKey Variables (part 1) (3 720 observations) Variable Mean St. Dev. Minimum Maximum Whlprice (¢) 61.023 7.260 38.000 81.000 Retprice (¢) 111.870 8.708 85.100 142.500 Margin(¢) 15.829 5.748 -3.000 37.522 Retwg ($) 226.210 24.118 187.790 288.340 Prval ($,000) 84.401 56.950 25.600 298.900 Popden 5.854 4.580 0.746 23.671 (,000/sq mile) NSS 0.050 0.218 0.000 1.000 LAW 0.167 0.373 0.000 1.000 wt 0.011 0.103 0.000 1.000 AL 0.025 0.156 0.000 1.000 Tax(¢) 35.015 4.990 22.100 49.999 Time 47.000 26.849 1.000 93.000 94 Table 9. Descriptive Statistics of Key Variables (part 2) (3640 Observations) Name Mean St. Dev. Minimum Maximum (all values are in cents) Nretprit 76.984 7.212 51.533 101.150 ANRetprit -0.034 2.414 -13.643 ·18.100 Whlpriceit 61.047 7.328 38.000 81.000 ' Whlpricei,t-1 61.234 7.071 38.000 81.000 Whlpricei,t-2 61.415 6.805 38.000 81.000 A Whlprice+it 0.495 0.873 0.000 11.700 A Whlprice -it -0.682 1.048 -13.800 0.000 A Whlprice+i 1_1 0:498 0.873 0.000 11.700 A Whlprice -i,t-1 -0.679 1.049 -13.800 0.000 TIME 48.000 26.271 3.000 93.000 95 APPENDIXC MOTOR FUELS TAXES BY CITY 96 Table 10 .. Motor Fuels Taxes and Computational Formulas as of Dec. 27, 1993 (part 1) City sT· FT Misc.Per Sales Tax State Local Sales Tax Formula (¢) (¢) .. Gallon Base Sales Sales Tax(¢) (STB) Tax Tax (¢) (%) (%) Albuqurque 23 18.4 N/A N/A Atlanta 7.5 18.4 N/A RP-ST 4 1 STB - (STB/1.05) Baltimore 23.5 18.4 N/A N/A Birmingham 18 18.4 1 N/A Boston 21 18.4 N/A N/A Buffalo 22.24 18.4 N/A RP-8 4.5 4 STB - (STB/1.08) Cheyenne 9 18.4 N/A N/A Chicago 19 18.4 NIA RP-ST 6.25 1.75 STB - (STB/1.08) Cleveland 22 18.4 N/A N/A Dallas 20 18.4 N/A N/A Denver 22 18.4 N/A N/A Des Moines 20 18.4 NIA N/A Detroit 15 18.4 N/A RP-16 4 STB - (STB/1.04) Houston 20 18.4. N/A N/A Indianapolis 15 18.4 N/A RP-ST-FT 5 STB - (STB/1.05) Kansas City 13.03 18.4 N/A N/A Los Angeles 17 18.4 N/A RP 7.25 1 STB - (STB/1.0825) Memphis 20 18.4 N/A N/A Miami 11.8 18.4 10.3 N/A Milwaukee 23.2 18.4 N/A N/A Minneapolis 20 18.4 N/A N/A New York 22.24 18.4 N/A RP-8 4.5 4.25 STB - (STB/1.0825) New Orleans 20 18.4 N/A N/A Newark 10.5 18.4 4 N/A 97 Table 10. Motor Fuels Taxes and Computational Formulas as of Dec. 27, 1993 (part2) Norfolk 17.5 18.4 N/A N/A Okla. City 17 18.4 N/A N/A Omaha 24.4 18.4 N/A N/A Pheonix 18 18.4 N/A N/A Philadelphia 22.35 18.4 N/A N/A Pittsburgh 22.35 18.4 N/A N/A Portland 24 18.4 N/A N/A Salt Lk. City 19 18.4 N/A N/A San Antonio 20 18.4 N/A N/A San Diego 17 18.4 N/A RP 7.25 0.5 STB - (STB/1.0775) San Francisco 17 18.4 N/A RP 7.25 1.25 STB - (STB/1.085) Seattle 23 18.4 N/A N/A St. Louis 13.03 18.4 N/A N/A Tulsa 17 18.4 N/A N/A Wash., D.C. 20 18.4 N/A N/A Wichita 18 18.4 N/A N/A ST = State per Gallon Tax FT = Federal per Gallon Tax RP = Retail Price N/A =Not Applicable • Some state taxes vary during during the sample period . .. Prior to Oct. 1, 1993, the Federal Gasoline Tax was 14.1 cents. Sources: Federal Highway Administration, Monthly Motor Fuel Reported by States (various da~es); The Road Information Program, 1993 State Highway Funding Methods; American Petroleum Institute, "State Gasoline Excise Tax Rankings - May 4, 1993 ". 98 APPENDIXD SALES BELOW COST LAWS BY STATE 99 Tablell. Sales Below Cost Laws by State State Sales Below Cost Law Minimum Markup Provision Alabama " Arizona California Colorado " District of Columbia Florida " Georgia Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Louisiana Maryland Massachusetts " " Michigan Minnesota Missouri " Montana " " Nebraska New York New Mexico New Jersey " Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennslyvania Tennessee " " Texas Utah " " Virginia Washington Wisconsin Wyoming 1 t/ denotes the eXIstence o:t a :Sales tle1ow Cost Law or MlDllllum Markup .Provision 100 APPENDIXE REGRESSION RESULTS OF EQUATION 4.1 101 Table 12. Full Regression Results of Equation 4.1 (part 1) Dependent Variable = Margin Independent Variable Retwg Prval Popden NSS LAW WI w2 w3 w4 Ws w6 w7 Ws w9 WIO Wn wl2 Wn Wt4 Wts wl6 wl7 Wts wl9 W2o W21 W22 · w23 W24 W2s w26 W21 W2s w29 W3o W31 . w32 Coefficient Value -0.007 0.040 -0.113 5.810 0.841 -12.254 -13.762 -16.262 -15.231 -13.930 -14.337 -15.000 -14.924 -13.175 -13.286 -12.923 .-13.016 -11.736 -10.067 -8.356 -7.439 -5.815 -7.333 -8.138 -7.545 -7.271 -8.768 -9.979 -11.259 -11.190 -9.907 . -7.759 -7.641 -8.132 -8.820 -8.642 -8.500 t-statistic -0.545 6.053 -2.148 5.732 1.976 -18.320 -20.680 -24.510 -23.010 -21.080 -21.730 -22.750 -22.650 -20.000 -20.170 -19.630 -19.770 -17.830 -15.290 -12.700 -11.300 -8.836 11.140 -12.370 -11.460 -11.050 -13.320 -15.160 -17.110 -17.000 -15.050 -11.790 -11.610 -12.360 -13.400 -13.130 -12.920 102 Table 12. Full Regression Results of Equation 4.1 (part 2) Independent Variable Coefficient Value w33 w34 W3s w36 W37 W3s w39 W4o W41 W42 w43 w44 W4s w46 w47 W4s W49 Wso Wsl Ws2 Ws3 Ws4 Wss Ws6 Ws7 Wss Ws9 W6o w61 w62 w63 w64 W6s w66 w67 W6s w69. W7o -7.802 -6.677 -4.119 -4.074 -3.488 -2.498 -2.824 -5.375 -5.645 -5.645 -5.598 -3.062 -3.004 -2.984 -2.986 -3.003 -6.995 -7.049 -7.086 -7.121 -7.158 -11.479 -11.509 -11.560 :-12.707 -12.751 -12.832 -12.889 -11.145. -11.193 -11.218 -11.234 -11.223 -6.510 -6.489 -6.624 -6.487 -4.485 t-statistic -11.860 -10.150 -6.259 -6.191 -5.300 -3.796 -4.291 -8.168 -8.577 -8.578 -8.507 -4.653 4.566 -4.535 -4.537 4.564 -10.630 -10.710 10.770 -10.820 -10.880 -17.450 -17.500 -17.580 -19.320 -19.400 -19.520 . -19.610 -16.970 -17.040 -17.090 -17.120 -17.120 -9.935 -9.911 -10.130 -9.931 -6.877 103 Table 12. Regression Results of Equation 4.1 (part 3) Independent Variable Coefficient Value w71 Wn w73 W74 W75 w76 w77 w1s W79 Wso Wsi W~2 Ws3 Ws4 Wss Ws6 Ws7 Wss Ws9 W9o· W91 w92 Constant Adjusted R2 = .49 3720 Observations -4.484 -4.482 -4.492 -4.518 -8.393 -8.372 -8.521 -8.529 -6.590 -6.618 -10.961 -10.978 -9.450 -9.453 -9.475 -9.497 ,.4.220 -4.225 -4.225 -4.222 -0.023 -0.021 22.549 t-statistic -6.887 -6.898 -6.930 -6.992 -13.030 -13.060 -13.360 -13.460 10.480 -10.620 -17.780 -18.050 -15.800 -16.140 -16.600 -17.190 -7.966 -8.425 -9.075 10.080 -0.064 -0.081 8.914