I ' I I I , TICKET PRICING IN THE ALPINE SKI INDUSTRY by Andrew Robert Gerl_ach A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Applied Economics MONTANA STATE UNIVERSITY Bozeman, Montana September 1990 ii APPROVAL of a thesis submitted by Andrew Robert Gerlach This thesis has been read by each member of the thesis committee and has been found to be satisfactory regarding content, English usage, format, citations, bibliographic style, and consistency, and is ready for submission to the College of Graduate studies. Date Chairperson, Graduate Committee Approved for the Major Department Date Chairperson, Graduate Committee ~pproved for the College of Graduate Studies Date Graduate Dean I I iii STATEMENT OF PERMISSION TO USE In presenting this thesis in partial fulfillment of the requirements for a master's degree at, Montana State University, I agree that the Library shall make it available to borrowers under rules of the Library. Brief quotations from this thesis are allowable without special permission, provided that accurate acknowledgement of source is made. Permission for extensive quotation from or reproduction of this thesis may be granted by my major professor, or in his absence, by the Dean of Libraries when, in the opinion of either, the proposed use of the material is for scholarly purposes. Any copying or use of the material in this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission·. Signature Date iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank the members of my thesis committee for their patience, time and direction: Dr. Ronald Johnson, Terry Anderson, and Mike Kehoe of my committee for their patience, insight, and guidance. In particular, I wish to thank, my ch~irman, Dr. Johnson, for the overall direction and commentary which were essential to the completion of this paper. I also would like encouraged and aided me. to thank my parents who always Most of all I must express my appreciation to Teresa Brock who continually supported and aided me throughout the process of writing this thesis. v TABLE OF CONTENTS Page APPROVAL. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . • . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . i i STATEMENT OF PERMISSION TO USE..................... iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . • . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . i v TABLE OF CONTENTS. . . . . . . . • . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v LIST OF TABLES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi LIST OF FIGURES . ..•.................••....... ~ . . . . . vii ABSTRACT • ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.. CHAPTER: 1. INTRODUCTION TO SKI-LIFT PRICING .......... . 2. SKI-LIFT PRICING, LITERATURE REVIEW ....... . 3. BARRO & ROMER TESTED AND QUESTIONED ....... . 4. MONOPOLISTIC SKI-LIFT PRICING •............. 5. MARKET POWER and SKI-LIFT PRICING PRACTICES REFERENCES •.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••...•...... APPENDICES . ........•••....•........................ A: Data Set ................................ . B: Computer program •••••••••.••.•••.••.••..• viii 1 5 25 41 57 68 72 73 76 vi LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1. Variables; Means and Standard Deviations ..... . 31 2. 2SLS Regression Results •..••......•........... 32 3. Price Discriminatory Ride and Lift Ticket Revenue . ••....................•...•........... 55 4. Airfare and Lodging Packages ...•...•.......•.. 63 5. Data, Regions 1-5 ............................ . 74 I I I vii LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1. Demand Increase . ............................ . 2. Supply Increase . ............................ . 3. Ride-Ticket verses Lift-Ticket Revenue ...... . 46 4. Non-Linear Demands •.......•••.•.••........... 51 J i viii ABSTRACT Alpine ski areas worldwide use daily lift-ticket pr1c1ng rather than individual ride-ticket pricing. Robert Barra and Paul Romer argue that the ski ride industry is a competitive market and that identical equilibriums and revenues are reached with either pricing method. They also argue that sticky lift ticket prices and lift-line queues are efficient. Lift-ticket pricing dominates because of lower monitoring costs. Tests of their model's predictions, however, do not support their model. A monopolistic ski-lift pricing model is developed. The monopoly model predicts that lift-ticket pricing would 'dominate the market due to its revenue generating advantages over ride-ticket pricing. Overall the monopoly model predicts the pricing policies that exist in the ski ride market better th~:m the competitive model of Barra and Romer. It is argued that lift-ticket pricing is an indication of the market power most ski areas possess. I i 1 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION TO SKI-LIFT PRICING For the recreational pleasure of skiing down a mountain, skiers travel to ski resorts and purchase lift tickets which provide them a day's access to lift rides. Why do ski areas rely almost exclusively on lift-ticket p~icing rather than ride-ticket pricing when each ski lift ride is actually a separate item? Is this simply the most efficient method of ride allocation in a competitive market, or rather an indication of market power? How can it be efficient to have lift lines, and if market power is present what are its implications? These are a few of the questions this thesis hopes to answer. While skiing is now a recreational activity, it was initially developed as a utilitarian form of transportation during the stone-age and remained primarily as such until the later part of the 19th century (Flower, 1976, p. 22). To facilitate alpine skiing's recreational aspect, uphill transportation was developed. Such uphill transportation first appeared in the 1870s in the form of mountain trains, but was not commonplace until the late 1930s, after the invention of the drag-lift (Flower, 1976, p.l14). In 1934 the first rope tow in America was set up at Woods toke, Vermont, and the 2 following year the first American resort specifically developed for skiers opened in sun Valley, Idaho. Over the years the demand for uphill lift transportation has continued to grow. In America alone there are now more than 20 million skiers who account for over 53 million annual skier visits at the more than 600 American ski resorts (Ski Industries America, 1984; Symonds, 1988) . In 1989 these ski resorts offered a combined lift capacity of over 19,600,000 rides per day at an average cost of $21.00 for a day lift ticket (Enzel, 1989; Goeldner, 1989). Lift-ticket pricing as opposed to ride-ticket pricing dominates the ski ride market worldwide. The former can be regarded as a two-part tariff with a lump sum fee (the lift ticket) required for the right to ski, and an explicit price per ride of zero. Ride-ticket pricing is a single-part tariff and requires a payment for each ride consumed. Barre and Romer (1987) developed a model of a competitive ski industry (reviewed in Chapter 2) and explained the dominance of lift-ticket pricing and other aspects of the ski ride industry. While most economists, such as Yoram Barzel (1974), would label long and persistent queues for a commodity as an inefficient allocative mechanism that dissipation rents, Barre and Romer argue that this is not the case with ski ride lift lines. Instead they argue that lift lines are not due to inefficiency in the pricing mechanism, but are a necessary feature which allows lift-ticket pricing to be an efficient 3 ride allocation scheme. While most models of supply and demand assume that efficient pricing dictates that prices fluctuate with demand or supply, Barro and Romer argue that due to the lift line ride allocation mechanism and a unitary demand elasticity, lift ticket prices may remain fixed. In their competitive model, ride-ticket pricing and lift-ticket pricing results in identical total revenues and equilibrium conditions. Barro and Romer argue that due to lower monitoring and set-up costs, lift-ticket pricing schemes dominate the market. While their model has many interesting features, tests of its predictive capabilities, which are reported in Chapter 3, yield ambiguous results, at best. It will be argued that the model's predictive faults appear due to inaccurate assumptions about the underlying market structure. To better explain ski ride pricing practices, a new model of the American alpine ski ride industry is developed in Chapter 4. For this model, it is assumed that each ski area possesses some degree of market power and can price as a monopolist. It is shown that under the assumption of monopolistic pricing, a ski area can generally generate greater revenues with lift-ticket pricing rather than with ride-ticket pricing, but not under all circumstances. The latter result contrasts with the outcome obtained by Oi (1974), whereby a two-part tariff (lift-ticket pricing) would always dominate. Nevertheless, this result is an anomaly, and as far as ski ride pricing studies are concerned, this aspect 4 is of minor importance since the conditions necessary for it to occur are uncommon. When compared to actual ski ride pricing practices, the monopoly model's revenue maximization principle provides a stronger explanation for the dominance of lift-ticket pricing policies than does Barre and Romer's cost minimization contentions. Further analysis of the monopoly model and its predictive advantages over Barre and Romer's competitive model are presented in Chapter 5. It is shown that another economic anomaly may occur in the alpine ski ride industry. This anomaly is that local skiers rather than tourists may be the ones discriminated against in terms of higher (lift ticket) prices. Overall, the monopoly model's predictive and explanatory capabilities are shown to be superior to those of the competitive model. It is argued that the dominance of lift-ticket pricing schemes is due to the market power that most ski areas possess. 5 CHAPTER 2 SKI-LIFT PRICING, LITERATURE REVIEW Contained in this chapter is a review of an article written by Barre and Romer (1987). Their article develops a competitive model of the alpine ski industry and challenges conventional wisdom by arguing that queues are not inefficient; lump-sum lift-ticket and per unit ride-ticket pricing policies result in identical revenues and equilibrium conditions; and fluctuations in demand need not require changes in lift-ticket pricing. To demonstrate their arguments, ride-ticket pricing is considered first, followed by an analysis of lift.;..ticket pricing. A comparison of the two pricing schemes reveals that they yield identical . revenues and equilibrium conditions. Lift-ticket pricing, however, is argued to be the pricing scheme of choice for ski areas due to lower monitoring and set-up costs. A deeper analysis of the Barro-Romer model shows how prices adjust to shifts in demand, differences across ski areas, transportation costs and skier preferences. The equations and notation offered in this chapter follows that employed by Barre and Romer. Consider a ski industry where price is charged on a per ride basis. Each of n homogeneous skiers, who differ only in \ I 6 their fixed costs of going skiing, face an industry comprised of J identical competitive ski areas. Each ski area operator has a fixed lift capacity, x, · and charges the same common price per ride, P. The marginal cost of a ride is assumed to be zero for the ski area. The result is an industry whose total supply, Jx, is perfectly inelastic in the short run. Each individual skier, i, seeks to maximize utility by consuming a combination of ski ri~es, qi, and all other goods, zi, subject to the budget constraint, Yi. The budget constraint is assumed to be comprised of the cost of qi ride tickets, the cost of all other goods, zi, the price of which are set to $1.00, and the lump sum costs of going skiing, ci. The latter is comprised of the opportunity cost of going skiing and travel and boarding expenses and is independent of the number of ski rides taken per day. Hence, the budget constraint is (2. 1) The demand for ski runs is described by a downward- sloping income compensated demand curve, qi=Di(P), where Pis the price per ride. The integral of the demand curve taken from zero to qi provides a monetary measure of the willingness to pay for the qi rides, (2.2) An individual will choose to ski as long as the total cost involved in consuming the qi runs, is less than or equal 7 to the gain that the individual receives from skiing qi runs, (2. 3) As long as the "net surplus" is greater than or equal to zero the individual will choose to ski. While all individuals are assumed to have identical demand functions, they do differ in their respective lump sum costs, ci. These fixed costs vary across individuals depending on their occupations and locations. Costs can also vary throughout the year. For example, during weekends and holidays when skiers are not working, the opportunity cost of time is often less. The distribution of the ci's across individuals is described by a cumulative distribution function Fs. The subscript s is a shift parameter which describes the changes in the lump sum costs at different times. On a given day, only those individuals whose net surpluses are positive will ski. When the fixed costs are high, as during weekdays and non-vacation periods, relatively few individuals will have positive net surpluses and choose to ski. The actual number of skiers who choose to ski, N, therefore is a function of the price per ride and distribution of the lump sum costs, (2. 4) N • N(P, s) . Equilibrium, in a ride-ticket pricing system, is determined by the number of rides provided by the ski industry, Jx, and the total number of rides demanded by the 8 ski community, qiN. Therefore, the equilibrium conditions are (2. 5) Jx = D(P) * N(P, s). With lift capacity fixed in the short run, this condition will determine the equilibrium price per ride that each competitive firm takes as a given. For equilibrium to be reached the price per ride, P, must fluctuate in the same direction as demand, D(P). Over the long run, when capacity is allowed to fluctuate, this equilibrium condition also determines the price per ride. As capacity increases, ceteris paribus, the price per ride will decrease. Competition in the industry requires that the firms take this equilibrium ride ticket price, P, as a given. Barre and Romer demonstrate that these ride-ticket equilibrium conditions are identical, in terms of cost of skiing and allocation of rides, to that arrived at with a two part pricing system. The two-part tariff consists of a lump sum entry fee, the lift ticket, and an explicit price per ride set equal to zero. The identical equilibria are reached due to unique properties intrinsic in the lift-ticket pricing scheme's allocation of rides. Under two-part pricing, as with ride-ticket pricing, each individual will choose to ski as long as the gain from skiing is not exceeded by the sum of the lift ticket price and the costs represented by ci. While the explicit zero marginal price per ride appears to provide no constraint on the number of rides available per skier, an \ , I 9 area's lift capacity will constrain the number of rides that each skier will receive. Each skier, through the use of the lift line allocation mechanism, receives the same number of rides. In other words, though the skier faces an explicit zero marginal cost per ride he also faces a queue. The number of rides per skier per day is determined by the speed at which he skis down a run, by the number of other skiers at the hill, the rate at which they ski, and the rate at which the lifts can transport skiers up the hill. If it is assumed that all skiers ski at the same pace, each skier will receive the same quantity of rides. Under this assumption the number of runs that any one individual skier can make is solely determined by the number of skiers at the hill, n, and the lift capacity of the hill, x (in rides per day). The quantity of rides that each skier receives, qi, is simply the area's lift capacity, x, divided by the number of skiers at the lifts, n. It is assumed that facing a zero marginal price per ride each individual prefers a greater number of rides than is available. As a consequence, a lift line will arise and allocation by queuing will occur. It will be shown that this queuing form of ride allocation creates no inefficiencies due to an assumed zero opportunity cost of time for a skier at a hill. The assumption that the opportunity cost of time for an individual waiting in a lift line is zero is not intuitive. Barro and Romer do not imply that the overall opportunity cost 10 of.time for an individual is zero. They argue that when an individual is making a decision to go skiing, the individual's opportunity cost of time can be great. This opportunity cost of time is included in the fixed co~ts of going skiing, c 1, and is encompassed in the shift parameter, s. What Barre and Romer assume is that having made the decision to go skiing once the skier is at the ski resort he has a new approximately zero opportunity cost of time. They assume that the "time spent at a ski area or amusement park is inherently valuable so that the cost of time spent in the queue is approximately z~ro."(p. 876) Barre and Romer (pp. 877-878) state further that "people do not care directly about time spent waiting in lift lines . They would prefer shorter lines because they would prefer more rides; but given a fixed number of rides, they are indifferent between spending time outdoors in line or indoors in the loqge." The individual is assumed not to be contemplating other possibilities for the use of his time but rather how many runs will be obtained. With a zero opportunity cost of time, the lift line efficiently allocates a fixed number of rides equally to all skiers. The efficiency of the lift line will be demonstrated later. Consider now, the pricing decision of each individual ski firm. As with ride-ticket pricing, each individual skier will only choose to ski at a particular area as long as the total gain from skiing exceeds the total costs. In a lift-ticket pricing ski industry, an individual facing the choice between \' ' I ~ , ,. 11 two areas, j and k, will choose the area from which he will have the greater consumer surplus. Each area is initially assumed to have identical lift capacities, x, and therefore able to offer a fixed quantity of rides per individual per day. Given each area's fixed lift capacity, the quantities, qi and qk, are determined solely by the number of individuals choosing to ski at each area. Homogeneous individuals will be indifferent between the two areas as long as the net surpluses are equal. Therefore, (2. 6) where,n is the lump sum lift ticket price. Once a ski area chooses its lift ticket price, the number of skiers adjusts to keep the net surpluses at each area equal.. In other words, a ski hill is a price taker with respect to the reservation value of net surplus. This reservation value of net surplus, which is the skier's gain from skiing minus the associated total costs, dictates a unique inverse relationship between the lift ticket price, n j , and the number of skiers at area j . As ski area j increases its lift ticket price, the number of skiers will decline, and the number of rides per skier increases so as to maintain the equality of net surplus across the different ski areas. Assuming that a ski area's marginal cost per ride is zero, a firm attempting to maximize profits given a fixed capacity will simply maximize total revenue (Hirshleifer, 12 1988, pp. 124-25). Total revenue is defined as the product of the lift ticket price and the number of skiers. To maximize revenue, a ski area will set its lift ticket price such that qj = xjnj = o· 1 (xjnj), the elasticity of nj with respect to11: J can be derived by implicit differentiation of the reservation value of net surplus (the left side of equation 2.6), that is, (2.7) an. -1 __ J =------- a1t j D_l ( X ) ( .2£.) n. n2 J j Multiplying both sides of this equation by -~~ - yields the n elasticity of the number of skiers with respect to the lift ticket price, (2. 8) Maximization of revenue requires the ski area to operate such that the left hand side of ( 2. 8) is equal to -1. Upon rearranging terms, (2. 9) Dividing (2.9) by qj indicates that the average price per ride is equal to the marginal willingness to pay for the q/h ride, (2.10) 1t J - D_l ( qj) . qj Since D" 1 (qj) is simply the inverse demand function, the i I 13 average price per ride in lift-ticket pricing is equal to the effective price per ride, ,.. 1t . pj = _J. qj (2.11) It follows that the fixed number of rides available per skier at area j under a lift-ticket pricing policy is equal to the quantity that would be demanded at the "effective" price per ride Pi, if each ride were sold individually, i.e., (2.12) Since each ski area is identical and since skiers have homogeneous demands, equilibrium dictates that each area offer the same lift ticket price, and serve the same quantity of skiers, each at the same effective price per ride. On any given day the number choosing to ski is a function of the effective price per ride and the fixed cost shift parameter, (2. 13) N=N(P, s) . Market equilibrium requires that the total number of rides offered, Jx, equal the total number of rides demanded, where the latter is the product of the number of rides demanded per individual, D(ft) , and the number of individuals, N(P, s) . (2 .14) Jx = D (F) *N(P, s) . This lift-ticket market equilibrium is equivalent to the ride- ticket market equilibrium described in equation (2.5). However, the price per ride, P, has been replaced with the 14 effective price per ride, P. Substitution of equation (2.12} into equation (2.11} dictates that the lift ticket price is determined by the effective price per ride. (2. 15) The lift ticket price, as equation (2.15} shows, is determined by the product of the equilibrium effective price per ride and the number of rides each skier receives. This effective price per ride, P, for q rides, would equal the equilibrium price per ride, P, reached with ride-ticket pricing. The identical effective price per ride with both ticketing schemes allows each skier to receive the same quantity of rides at the same total cost regardless of the pricing scheme used. With a lift ticket scheme, the individual rides are just packaged together. The equality of ride ticket price and effective price per ride is what Barre and Romer (p. 8 7 5) refer to as the "package-deal effect." The package-deal effect refers to the situation wherein an individual is indifferent between purchasing a group of items in a pre-determined package or on a per-unit basis. It would occur if the individual is offered each item at a price, the sum of which would equal the price of the same items offered as a package with the transaction costs of the two purchases being equal. In the current context, an individual would be indifferent between purchasing twenty ride tickets at a price per ride of $1.50, or a lift 1 ! 1. ' 15 ticket with a constraint of twenty rides for the price of $30.00. Since the same equilibrium-is reached with a ride-ticket pricing system without queues and a lift-ticket pricing system with queues, the queues must result in no efficiency loss. Skiers and ski areas make their allocative decisions, not on the explicit zero marginal price per ride but rather on the implicit marginal effective price per ride, P~D-1 (q). Each competitive firm maximizes revenue with respect to the reservation value of net surplus, resulting in an identical allocation of rides and cost per ride as that of an equilibrium in the ride-ticket pricing scheme. The lift ticket is simply a package deal whereby the consumer is offered a group of q rides, each at an effective price per ride of F. The total revenue received by the ski area and cost to the skier are the same with either pricing scheme. Since both ride-ticketing and lift-ticketing policies result in the same revenue, the method that minimizes monitoring and set-up costs is chosen. It is argued that lift-ticket pricing is chosen because ride-ticket pricing would require greater costs to set and enforce contracts. Barre and Romer believe that only with ride-ticketing would ski areas be required to continually change prices and monitor skiers. With ride-ticketing, skiers would be required to purchase a ticket for every ride up the ! '· ' i I I I ' i I, ' 16 hill or purchase a group of tickets ahead of time. The latter, however, would still require some physical action be taken upon a skier's ticket for every ride up the hill. Furthermore, Barre and Romer stress that a ride-ticketing system would require a larger menu of prices than a lift-ticketing system. In practice the demand for ski rides is not known with certainty at the beginning of the day. Throughout the day demand can change and ride-ticket pricing would need to be adjusted. For example, early in the day demand and price could be low, while later in the day demand could increase. To totally eliminate lift line queues, the ride-ticketing ski hill would have to constantly monitor the demand for ski rides and change the ride price accordingly. The lift-ticket pricing scheme with its lift line ride allocation mechanism, however, results in an automatic adjustment in the implicit price per ride through increases in the queue, thereby reducing adjustment costs. But, Barre and Romer also assume that the price elasticity of demand is approximately equal to unity. As is shown below, this automatic adjustment in the effective price per ride is such that lift ticket prices would seldom need adjustment. To demonstrate how this automatic adjustment operates, assume, as Barre and Romer do, that an increase in aggregate . demand results from a change in the shift parameter, s. The shift is caused by a decrease in the fixed costs of going skiing, which could be due to a decrease in the opportunity i I 17 cost of time associated with the weekend and holiday periods. Such a shift increases the number of people whose reservation value of net surplus exceeds the lift ticket price. As this occurs there will be more skiers per area. With a fixed capacity and an increase in demand, each skier will receive fewer rides. This results in an automatic increase in the effective price per ride. When the elasticity of demand with respect to the effective price per ride is unitary (absolute value), no lift ticket price change is necessary. A very large portion of Barro and Romer's analysis deals with what they see as the presence of a stickiness in lift ticket prices over time and across areas. During the course of a season, such as over weekends and during Christmas, the demand for skiing varies, but lift ticket prices are seen by Barro or Romer to remain fixed. Analysis of equation (2.15) reveals the conditions whereby the effective price per ride under the lift-ticket pricing scheme can vary in the same direction as demand without any adjustments to the lift-ticket price. Taking the derivative of equation (2.15) with respect to the effective price per ride yields the incremental effect of a change in the lift ticket price due to a change in the effective price per ride, (2. 16) d1t = PD1
+ D(:P} •
c1P
Upon rearranging terms, it can be seen that the degree and
direction of change in the equilibrium lift ticket price
I
i i
I I I
18
depends on the elasticity of demand for rides with respect to
the effective price per ride,
(2.17)
Since all individuals have the same demand function, 1lv,P' also
defines the individual's elasticity of demand for rides with
respect to the effective price per ride. Equation (2.17) shows
the profit maximizing change in lift ticket price due to an
incremental change in the effective price per ride. When
aggregate demand increases the effective price per ride will
automatically increase. But, depending on the elasticity of
demand, the profit maximizing lift ticket price may increase,
decrease or stay the same.
The pricing behavior due to an increase in demand can
better be understood with the aid of Figure (1). In this
figure ski areas have a total lift capacity, Jx, and face a
market for ski rides which is comprised of individual demand
curves such as di. The initial aggregate market demand is D0
which later increases to D1 as the number of skiers increases.
The initial lift ticket price is, P"c,aq0 0, which is determined
by the effective price per ride P0 , and the quantity of rides
per individual q 0 • An increase in demand from D0 to D1 , ceteris
paribus, would not necessitate any change in the lift ticket
price if a unitary elastic demand existed. With a unitary
demand the effective price per ride increases, but this
increase is exactly offset by a decrease in the number of
I ' I
I I.
G)
(,)
·;::
c.
I
I
" : Po --------r----
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
19
Jx
0._----~--~--------------------~ q1 q 0
Jx
Number of Rides
Figure 1. Price Response to Demand Increase
I ' !
20
rides per individual, i.e., P0 aq0 0 = P1 b% 0 . If demand were
elastic, the increase in demand would dictate a decrease in
lif-t ticket prices because the decrease in rides would more
than offset the increase in the effective price per ride. That
is, P1 b%0 < P0 aq0 0 • If there existed an inelastic demand for
rides with respect to the effective price per ride, lift
ticket prices would increase as demand increased, i.e.,
Barre and Romer conclude that constant lift ticket prices
result because the elasticity must remain very near unity
throughout most of the year. Any potential increases in
revenue from a lift ticket price change would be offset by the
menu costs incurred from the price change. Barre and Romer
infer that only in cases of very low demand, such as at the
end of the season, does the elasticity of demand vary enough
from unity to justify a change in lift'ticket prices. Their
model also predicts that there should be less variation in
lift ticket prices across areas and seasons, than in the
number of skiers or length of lift lines. While these
predictions are relative statements, Barre and Romer leave the
impression that elasticity of demand must be very close to
unity.
The foundations of the Barre and Romer model described
so far were derived upon the assumption that all ski areas are
identical and that skiers differ only in their fixed cost
21
involved in going skiing. As these assumptions are relaxed to
allow for differences in lift capacities, travel costs, and
heterogenous individuals, the basic conclusions do not change.
Barra and Romer also allow lift capacities to vary
considerably across areas, but lift ticket prices remain
fixed. This can be explained with the use of what they refer
to as the homogeneity effect. The homogeneity effect with
lift-ticket pricing refers to the case where there are
identical skiers who are free to choose from among J ski areas
which differ only in their respective lift capacities. The
skiers. will sort themselves amongst the various areas such
that, in equilibrium, the number of skiers at each area will
vary one-for-one with their respective capacities and where
each individual will pay an identical effective price per
ride. If ski area B has twice the lift capacity as area A,
area B will have twice as many skiers, and skiers at each area
will receive the same number of rides. Skiers will adjust
themselves between the areas until the net surplus at all the
areas are equal. Thus, lift ticket prices will be identical
across all ski areas.
This same homogeneity effect allows for one lift ticket
being good across all the lifts at one area on a given day.
The runs at a hill that have the greatest demand would also
. have the longest lines. In equilibrium a lift that provides
a run that offers twice the distance as a neighboring run
would be accompanied by a lift line that would allow for only
22
half the number of runs as the neighboring run. The net
surplus in equilibrium must still be equal across every lift
at a hill, as well as across all hills, otherwise an
individual could gain surplus by choosing to ski at a
different lift or area. Ski areas maximize revenue subject to
the reservation value of net surplus, and skiers choose
amongst the areas to keep the net surplus equal at all areas.
Competition ensures that net surpluses are equated as equation
(2.6) dictates.
To further expand on this point, assume two identical
areas existed at different distances from a metropolitan area
but charged the same lift ticket price. The hill at the closer
proximity to the metropolitan area will have a larger amount
of skiers. The equilibrium condition will be reached when the
difference in travel costs associated with reaching the
farther hill is made up for by the gain in extra rides
available at the distant hill. This results in an equilibrium
condition where the net surpluses once again are equal at both
of the areas. As described previously, the elasticity of
demand for rides with respect to the effective price per ride
determines the effect of a demand change on the optimal lift
ticket price. Over the range where the elasticity is unity
there need be no difference in lift price associated with the
difference in travel costs. The Barro and Romer model,
however, would predict that in the presence of an elastic
demand efficient pricing would dictate a lift ticket price
23
that is higher the more distant the hill. An inelastic demand
would dictate a higher priced ticket the closer the hill. As
always, the elasticity of demand with respect to the effective
price per ride determines the change in the "gain from skiing"
with a change in the number of rides available and therefore
determines the equilibrium lift ticket prices.
As a final point, Barro and Romer consider the existence
of two different types of skiers, avid skiers who demand a
greater number of rides at every price than less avid skiers.
The queuing mechanism intrinsic in the single lift-ticket
pricing scheme allocates rides across ski slopes equally among
each skier and cannot differentiate between the differences in
demands of the various skiers. The solution posed by Barro and
Romer is that two types of ski areas will develop such that
each area will either cater to the avid or less avid skier.
The avid hill will charge a higher lift ticket price such that
fewer skiers will choose it. Thus, it will be able to offer a
greater number of rides for each avid skier than the less
expensive ski area.
To summarize, Barro and Romer argue that lift-ticket
pricing leads to no inefficiencies even though the explicit
marginal price per ride is zero and queues exist. The lift
ticket equilibrium in this competitive market is simply a
package of the same quantity of rides and effective price per
ride that would be demanded and offered under ride-ticket
pricing. The lift-ticket pricing policy is used because it can
24
be implemented with lower monitoring and set-up costs as
compared to a ride-ticket pricing system. Skiers adjust
themselves across areas to keep the net surplus equal at all
areas. The competitive ski areas must take the skiers
reservation value of net surplus as a given, but are free to
set their lift ticket price. Importantly, the Barre and Romer
model predicts that if the elasticity of demand is unity, ski
areas will not adjust their lift ticket prices even with
predictable fluctuations in demand. Barre and Romer leave the
clear impression that lift ticket prices are sticky and that
queuing is a prime method for allocating rides. Furthermore,
in their model ski areas are price takers with respect to the
effective price per ride. Each competitive area has no market
power. Thus, an area has no ability to price discriminate
across demands.
I ! I
25
CHAPTER 3
BARRO & ROMER TESTED AND QUESTIONED
Barro and Romer (1987) assert that lift ticket prices are
"sticky" and that this stickiness is due to a unitary
elasticity of demand. As described previously, with a unitary
elasticity of demand with respect to the effective price per
ride, ski areas would not need to adjust lift ticket price
with changes in demand. Lift ticket prices would remain fixed
over time and across areas because as demand changed skiers
would simply adjust themselves until the net surpluses are
once again equal. The assertion of a unitary elasticity and
sticky prices can be tested in two ways. The assertion that
the elasticity is unitary can be tested with statistical
analysis, and the stickiness of lift ticket prices can be
tested by comparing prices over time and across areas.
The pricing behavior of a competitive ski area in Barro
and Romer's model and its implication for testing can better
be understood with the aid of Figure (2). There, ski areas
have an initial market lift capacity of Jx0 which is later
increased to Jx1 • The ski areas face an aggregate market
demand function, Dm, which is comprised of individual demand
functions such as di. At the initial lift capacity the lift
ticket price is, P0aq0 0 , which is determined by the effective
I '
.I
(J)
(.)
·;::::
c..
" Po 1
A I
p1 -----------------t--
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
26
Om
di
0~----------~--~---------r----~------------~
Jxo
Number of Rides
Figure 2. Price Response to Capacity Increase
27
price per ride ~' and the quantity of rides per individual,
q 0 • As lift capacity increases to Jx1 the effective price per
ride would decrease from ~ to P1 and the number of rides per
individual would increase from q0 to q 1 • An increase in
capacity from Jx0 to Jx1 would not necessitate any change in
lift ticket price if a unitary elastic demand with respect to
the effective price per ride existed. With a unitary demand,
the capacity increase would have no effect on lift ticket
price because the decrease in the effective price per ride is
exactly offset by an increase in the number of rides per
individual; P0 aq0 0 - P1 b%0. If the capacity increase resulted
in a lift ticket price increase it would suggest the presence
of an elastic demand because the increase in rides would more
than offset the decrease in the effective price per ride. That
is P~b%0 > P0 aq0 0. If the lift ticket price is inversely
affected by an increase in capacity, an inelastic demand would
be suggested. In such a case, P1 b% 0 < P0 a q 0 0 .
Similarly if the number of skiers increase with a fixed
capacity, the number of rides per individual decreases and
therefore the effective price per ride increases. If the
correlation between the number of skiers and the lift ticket
price is zero, a unitary elasticity would be implied. Thus,
skier visits should have a positive effect on lift price if
the demand is inelastic or a negative effect if demand is
elastic, holding capacity constant.
These relationships between lift ticket price, capacity
28
and skier visits suggests a simple empirical specification to
test whether the effective price elasticity of demand is equal
to unity as Barra and Romer contend. This specification can be
described as
( 3 . 1) 1t- a + b 1 V+ b 2 C+ 1J. t:.
Here,1t is the lift ticket price. The number of skier visits
is represented by v, while c represents ski area lift
capacity. Equation (3.1} can be estimated with a regression of
lift ticket price on skier visits and capacity. This
regression estimates the coefficients of visits and capacity
and their significance on price. From these results Barra and
Romer's assertion of a unitary elasticity can be tested as was
described with Figures (1} and (2).
Estimation of (3.1} with ordinary least squares,
however, would result in biased estimates due to the
simultaneous interaction of the two endogenous variables,
visits and price (Rao and Miller, 1971} . Since price is
dependent on visits, and visits is dependent on-price, visits
are correlated with the error term, ut, thereby causing a
violation of one of the basic assumptions of the classical
linear regression model. Therefore, a two-stage least squares
regression technique, which produces consistent unbiased
estimates of equation (3.1}, is used. The two-stage least
squares technique replaces visits with a computed instrumental
value that is intended to eliminate the stochastic elements
that are correlated with the error term.
1
! !
29
The effectiveness of this technique is dependent on the
ability to develop an instrumental variable which is highly
correlated to visits but not correlated with price. The
variables other than lift ticket price which can have a
significant impact on the yearly number of skier visits are:
weather, population, personal income, and the skiing region.
Weather was included to capture effects on skier visits that
are due to weather conditions. The population variable was
included to capture any fluctuations in skier visits due to
demographic changes. Since personal income can affect the
opportunity cost of going skiing it also was included. Eastern
ski areas have many lifts with small vertical displacement
while western ski areas have fewer lifts with large vertical
displacement. Since the capacity data (VTF) used in this
analysis is the product of the vertical displacement and
number of rides, regional dummy variables were included to
capture effects due to these regional variations.
Data on lift ticket prices were obtained for the skiing
seasons 1978-79 thru 1988-89 (Goeldner, 1978-88). These
figures were only available as yearly average regional lift
ticket prices including all discounts offered. The five
regions covered are: the Northwest, East, Midwest, Rockies and
the West. The nominal lift ticket prices were deflated by the
Consumer Price Index using 1972 as the base year. Data on
total yearly alpine area skier visits were obtained which
correspond to the regions and time series lift ticket price
30
data (Kottke, 1978-88}. The capacity data were available from
the magazine Ski Area Management (1978-88}. These figures are
tabulated by the magazine as total vertical transfer feet per
hour, VTF, and compiled to coincide with the above regions.
Vertical Transfer Feet per Hour, or VTF, is the product of a
chairlift's rated capacity in skiers per hour, and the
vertical displacement of the lift ride.
The data used to estimate the instrumental variable were
gathered from a number of sources. The average number of
operating days per season, which was used as the proxy for
weather conditions, was available from the annual Economic
Analysis of North American Ski Areas (Goeldner, 197 8-88)
Regional population figures in the 14-44 year old age group
were taken from the Statistical Abstracts of the U.S. (U.S.
Department of Commerce, 1978-88}. This population dataset was
chosen because according to a pair of studies approximately 80
percent of all skiers are in the 14-44 year old age group and
76.8 % of all skiers ski within 500 miles of their home (Ski
Industries America, 1984). The regional average yearly per
capita Personal Income was developed from the Statistical
Abstracts of the u.s (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1978-88).
It was deflated with the Consumer Price Index with 1972 as the
base year.
Annual data for 11 seasons beginning in 1978-79 and five
regions yielded a time series database of 55 usable data
points per variable. Table (1} presents the means and standard
-I
I
I
\I }
I i
I ! I
' I
I
! }
i
1 I I
I I
I I
31
deviations for all the variables.
Table 1. Variables; Means and Standard Deviations.
VARIABLE MEAN STANDARD DEVIATION
Price 4.40 0.66
(1972 dollars)
Visits 16.685 15.563
(Millions)
Capacity 5.283 5.077
(Thousand VTF)
Weather 121.24 18.502
(Days of operation)
Population 33.499 35.041
(Millions)
Personal Income 4354.9 484.00
(1972 Dollars)
The results of the two-stage least square regression of
equation (3.1) with the data just described are reported in
table (2). The coefficient on the capacity variable is
significant and positive at the 5 9.,-0 level, while the
coefficient on skier visits is insignificant, providing
inconclusive results. As described with Figure (2) the
insignificance of visits on price supports the assertion of
unitary elasticity of demand. On the other hand, the positive
and significant coefficient on capacity suggests an
underlining elastic demand for rides. These results do not
provide consistent support for the assertion of a unitary
elasticity of demand.
1 l
32
Table 2. 2SLS Regression Results.
Variables Coefficient
Visits 0.26E-3
Capacity 0.44E-7
Dummy 1 0.40E-2
Dummy 2 0.19E-2
Dummy 3 -0.25E-2
Dummy 4 0.27E-2
* R-Squared Adjusted = 0.8782
t-ratio
0.728
7.112
2.813
1. 022
-1.456
-3.105
In addition to the above test, there are a number of
instances where Barre and Romer's assertion of unitary demand
elasticity resulting are at odds with real world lift-ticket
pricing practices. For example, Barre and Romer (p. 881) argue
that a substantial interval of time should exist "where lift
ticket prices would show little or no variation with demand."
While their statement is in relative terms many ski areas have
multiple prices and change lift ticket prices frequently. For
example, Breckenridge ski area in Colorado had 78 different
lift ticket prices during the 1988-89 season (Russell, 1989).
Breckenridge is not the only hill with such pricing policies.
The American Ski Association, an organization that offers lift
ticket discounts to club members, offers lift tickets from
many areas which change 10 times or more during the season
(American Ski Association, 1990). These price fluctuations
exist at every ski area. Most areas at least lower the face
value of their lift tickets or offer discounts off the face
value for weekday periods (Berry, 1990).
I
r I
I ,
I I
I ,
I
I I
I
33
Barro and Romer (p. 884) also assert that there is a
"cross-sectional stickiness" in lift ticket prices. However,
the 1987-88 Economic Analysis of North American Ski Areas
shows lift ticket prices that are anything but cross
sectionally sticky (Goeldner, 1988). The face value weekend
ski lift ticket prices vary from $10.00 to over $35.00 and the
average revenue per lift ticket ranged from $11.41 in the
midwest to $20.91 in California and Nevada. Lift-ticket
revenue per skier visit also varies greatly with respect to
area capacity. Areas of small capacity receive an average
revenue per lift ticket of $10.83 whereas areas with the
largest capacities receive revenues of over $23.00 per lift
ticket. These pricing differences would not be observed if the
homogeneity effect suggested by Barro and Romer were
prevalent.
The cross-sectional variation in lift ticket prices is
especially evident in the Wasatch Mountains east of Salt Lake
city, Utah where 7 major ski resorts are within a few miles of
one another (Ski Utah, 1989). Snowbird, the area closest to
Salt Lake City, charges $32.00 per lift ticket. A mile further
up Little Cottonwood canyon at Alta, a day's lift ticket sells
for $19.00. In the neighboring Big Cottonwood Canyon, Brighton
sel1s weekday lift tickets for $14.00 and weekend or holiday
tickets for $18.00. Across the canyon from Brighton at
Solitude, weekday lift tickets are $17.00 and holiday and
weekend tickets are $21.00. A single day's lift ticket good
I i
i
l I
I I
I
I I I .
i
I i
i i I
i I
34
for both Solitude and Brighton can be purchased for $28.00.
The ski resorts of Park City, Deer Valley and Park West, which
operate on the other side of the ridge from Brighton, have
substantially different lift ticket prices. These three areas
have lift tickets selling for $40.00, $35. oo and $24. oo
dollars, respectively. The pricing practices observed in the
Wasatch Range are clearly not cross-sectionally sticky.
Further, the higher prices for the interconnect lift-tickets
good for both Brighton and Solitude would not exist under
Barre and Romer's assumptions.
There are a number of additional assumptions in the Barre
and Romer model which seem at odds with actual behavior. For
example, Barre and Romer assume that the willingness to pay
per ski ride is independent of the number of skiers at a hill.
Given this assumption, the only determining factor in the
willingness to pay for a lift ticket is the number of rides
available per individual. There may, however, be an additional
congestion effect which is not accounted for in the Barre and
Romer model. This congestion effect is caused by a disutility
that each additional skier's presence imposes on every other
skier's overall skiing experience. As more people ski, the
queues are assumed to absorb each additional skier, while the
number of skiers on each run remains the same. A more
realistic assumption, borne out by observation, is that more
skiers create more crowded runs. Assuming that skiers prefer
to ski on uncrowded slopes, the value of each ride would be
I
I I
35
inversely related to the number of skiers at an area. The
inclusion of a congestion effect could negate Barra and
Romer's homogeneity effect.
Furthermore, this congestion effect can explain why ski
areas often limit the number of skiers during peak periods. As
Uel Gardner, manager of Wintergreen ski resort in Virginia,
puts it, "Another policy is to limit the number of skiers to
minimize overcrowding on the trails and to reduce the lift
line wait." (Ayers, 1989) Ski area operators, of course,
limit the number of skiers by raising price.
Another problem with the Barra and Romer model is that
lift lines may not always fluctuate with demand so as to
automatically adjust the effective price per ride. If the
number of skiers is restrained or if lift lines do not exist,
the automatic adjustment cannot take place. Only during the
holiday periods do most ski areas approach 100% utilization.
Utilization often drops to as low as 25% for destination
resorts and 50% for day areas during non-holiday periods
(McKinsey and Co., 1989). During the 1989-90 ski season,
Bridger Bowl near Bozeman, Montana, averaged 1208 skiers per
day (Travel Montana, 1989). With a capacity of 45,600 rides
per day, the average skier could have 38 rides per day and
face no.lift lines. In the Barra and Romer model a requirement
for equilibrium is that the total number of rides demanded
always equal the number supplied. A lift line must always
exist and be allowed to fluctuate with demand to automatically
I '
I ' i
l
36
adjust the effective price per ride with demand changes. They
argue that lift-tick~ts are chosen over ride tickets because
the automatic price adjustment lessens monitoring and set-up
costs. Since this automatic adjustment often cannot operate,
the cost advantages of lift-ticketing over ride-ticketing are
reduced or even negated.
There is another assumption that raises doubt that lift~
ticketing is simply chosen over ride-ticket pricing because of
lower monitoring costs. This assumption is that the
opportunity cost of time is negligible. Barre and Romer (p.
880) state that "if the typical skier's fixed cost, c, for
getting to the ski area is large, and if waiting in line is
preferred to spending time on other available activities" then
·a positive opportunity cost of time would be relatively
unimportant. Furthermore, they state that "skiers receive the
same number of rides at the same cost in each case. The same
people end up participating, and each ski area receives the
same revenue." (Barre and Romer, p. 879) What the Barre and
Romer model does not explain is, if the same number of people
are participating and receiving the same number of rides with
either pricing scheme, where will the people who stand in the
lift lines go under a ride-ticket pricing scheme? There are,
for example, restaurants at most ski areas. Thus with the
alternative activities to standing in lift lines that are
available at a ski resort, then the greater the opportunity
cost of time the less efficient the lift-line ride allocation
I I
37
system would be. A positive opportunity cost of time decreases
any advantage of lift-ticketing over ride-ticketing policy
because people would be willing to pay a price to avoid
waiting in line.
Consider now, that Barre and Romer's formulation of the
function assumes only the possibility of a rotating market
demand curve. Barre and Romer state (p. 877) "Overall, we can
write the number of persons N who choose to ski as a function,
of N = N(P,s) ." Here, (s) defines the shift parameter which
describes the changes in the distribution of the fixed costs,
ci, involved in going skiing. When the ci's are low, as during
weekends and holidays, many people will choose to ski. When
the fixed costs are higher, as during weekdays and non-holiday
periods, fewer people will choose to ski. The market demand
curve rotates outward (as shown in Figure (1)) as the fixed
costs decrease, and rotates inward as the fixed costs
increase. An alternative assumption would be to allow· rotating
as well as shifting demands. Early in the season when people
have not skied in a long time, their demand curves may be
relatively high. At the end of the season, after skiing all
winter, demands may shift inward. such behavior could explain
the large discounts on lift tickets at the end of the season
(Russell, 1990). But, if individual demands are shifting over
time, then Barre and Romer's·simple relationship between the
elasticity of demand and the lift-ticket price no longer
holds, and the empirical test offered in Table (2) does not
38
provide a test of whether the underlying elasticity of demand
is equal to unity.
Perhaps the most important assumption that shapes the
foundation of the Barre and Romer model is that individual ski
operators are price takers. Competition, which forces ski
areas to be price takers with respect to the effective price
per ride, is essential to the Barre and Romer model. There is
evidence that this assumption may not accurately describe the
alpine ski industry.
In the Barre and Romer model (p. 877), each consumer
faces a market comprised of J firms, each of which "have a
negligible impact on aggregate quantities." While over 600 ski
areas exist in the u.s., they are scattered and the travel
costs required to reach each can vary substantially (Enzel,
1989). The market that each skier faces is limited to those
areas where the total costs, including travel costs, are
similar, and exceeded by the consumer surplus received from
skiing at the hill. With scattered ski areas and positive
travel costs, there are likely to be many instances where a
skier's net surplus is negative, except at a few nearby areas.
This suggests that each ski area will possess some degree of
market power, and the price taking behavior that Barre and
Romer model is unlikely.
Furthermore, the presence of more than one ski area
operating in the same location is not enough to guarantee a
competitive marketplace, at least according to the supreme
39
Court. It was ruled that Aspen Skiing Co. monopolized the
market for downhill skiing services in Aspen, Colorado (Aspen
Ski Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 1985). While there
were two firms operating ski areas in the same general
location, the Court nevertheless found that Aspen Skiing Co.
possessed monopoly power.
The presence of market power can be further witnessed by
the price discriminating practices used throughout the alpine
ski ride industry. Phlips (1983, p. 6) defines price
discrimination as "two varieties of a commodity are sold to
two buyers at different net prices." Bridger Bowl near
Bozeman, Montana for example, offers coupons, for $ 5.00 off
of lift tickets, available only to skiers staying at local
hotels (Lippke, 1989). They also offer lift tickets for
$13.00, a 35 % savings, but only if the skier is willing to
purchase an item at Burger King. Most ski areas offer
discounts which are only available to skiers who join a
national ski club, such as the American Ski Association
(1990). As men~ioned earlier, Breckenridge ski a~ea had 78
different lift tickets during one season (Russell, 1989). It
is quite evident that lift tickets were commonly sold to
different customers for different prices on the same day. On
any given day, there are many different lift-ticket prices
offered to different individuals, for entry onto the same
hill.
This is just one more instance where it has been shown
I I
I
40
that the alpine ski market envisioned and modeled by Barro and
Romer differs substantially from the one that actually exists.
Regression analysis does not confirm the presence of a unitary
elasticity of demand, and analysis of pricing shows lift
ticket prices that are not sticky. Furthermore, lift lines
often do not exist so the automatic adjustment in the
effective price per ride cannot take place. Importantly, the
assumption of a competitive ski ride market appears tenuous.
41
CHAPTER 4
MONOPOLISTIC SKI-LIFT PRICING
In this chapter a model of a ski industry is developed in
which each ski area is assumed to posses market power. Both
simple monopolistic and price discriminatory pricing are
considered for ride-ticket and lift-ticket pricing. Comparison
of ride-ticket and lift-ticket pricing in the monopoly model
reveals that revenues derived using lift-ticket pricing
generally exceed those of ride-ticket pricing. The monopoly
model predicts that lift-ticketing would be the dominant
pricing scheme due to its revenue maximizing capabilities. In
contrast, Barre and Romer's competitive model shows ride and
lift-ticketing to result in identical equilibria and revenues
and that ski areas choose lift-ticket pricing on purely~a cost
minimization basis.
Skiers face a market that is limited to those areas
where the total costs, including travel costs, are exceeded by
the consumer surplus received from skiing at the hill. over
600 ski areas are scattered throughout the United States and
the travel costs required to reach each varies substantially,
depending upon a skiers location. With scattered ski areas,
scattered skiers, and positive travel costs, there are likely
many instances where a skier's choice set will be restricted
' I
1, }
42
to only local areas. This suggests that each ski area will
posses some degree of market power and be a price setter.
To capture this market structure, it will be assumed that
each ski area faces a market comprised of various identifiable
groups of skiers, comprised of Ni skiers. The skiers are
assumed to have homogenous demand characteristics within a
group, but these characteristics vary across groups. As in
Barro and Romer, skiers can differ in their demand for ski
runs across groups but not in the time it takes them to ski
each ski run. This assumption allows every skier at a hill
using a lift-ticket pricing scheme to receive the same
quantity of rides. The queuing mechanism remains the method by
which a ski area using lift-ticket pricing can distribute a
fixed number of rides equally to all skiers.
Each monopolistic ski area has the option of using ride
ticket pricing, where each ride is sold individually at a
single price, P, or lift-ticket pricing with a lump-sum entry
fee and a zero price per ride. The lift-ticket pricing scheme
is designed to capture the entire net consumer surplus and
therefore cannot exceed the gain minus the fixed costs of
skiing. For simplicity in this analysis, however, fixed costs
are ignored. With a fixed capacity of K rides and a marginal
cost per ride that is assumed to be zero, the ski area will
.choose the ride-ticket or lift-ticket pricing scheme that
maximizes revenue.
This comparison of a single and two-part tariff differs
' \
43
from that analyzed by Oi (1971) in his Disneyland ride pricing
model. Ride allocation in Oi' s model allows the number of
rides allocated per individual to vary across individuals with
either pricing scheme. With the per individual ride
allocation mechanism of Oi's model, two-part tariff revenue
always exceed single-part tariff revenue. Unlike oi•s
Disneyland model, a ski area can differentiate the number of
rides offered to each individual only with ride-ticket
pricing. With lift-ticket pricing the ski lift line allocates
rides equally across all skiers. This lift-ticket ride
allocation mechanism constrains the revenue generating
capabilities of a lift-ticketing policy as compared to oi•s
model. This constraint suggests that conditions may exist
where ride ticket revenue exceeds lift-ticket revenue.
To analyze these revenue generating differences, consider
first a ski area that faces one group of N1 homogeneous
skiers. Assume that the inverse market demand function for
this group is linear and defined by
(4 0 1) b1Q P
-a1-]i
1 1
P1 is the individual price per ride, b 1 is each individual's
demand slope, and Q is the number of rides available to the
group. Under ride ticket pricing and a zero marginal cost of
supplying a ride, the ski area will operate at full capacity
as long as marginal revenue is greater than zero. Substituting
l
''}
44
B1 for b 1/N1 and the ski area ride capacity, K for Q, yields
the total ride-ticketing revenue
(4. 2) TRlrt - alK- B1K2.
Under a lift-ticket pricing policy the ski area can
generate revenue equal to the product of each individual lift
ticket price, 1t 1 , and the number of skiers N1 • Here, the
revenue maximizing ski area would set the lift ticket price
equal to each individual's total willingness to pay. If the
ski area charges anything greater than this, the skier would
choose not to ski. If anything less than this is charged, the
ski area is not maximizing revenue. The total willingness to
pay is equal to the area under the individual's demand curve
from zero to the rides available per individual, q 1 ; that is
(4. 3) 4> (q) -fa q1D-1 (q) dq.
Equating willingness to pay with lift ticket price and
assuming linear demands, we obtain
(4. 4) 1tl =a1 q1 - bl qt 2
The number of rides available per individual, q 1 , is
equal to K/N1 • The product of the lift ticket price 1t 1 , and
the number of skiers, N1 , as well as substitution of K/N1 for
q 1 , and B1 for b 1jN1 , results in a total lift ticket revenue,
(4. 5) TRlLT .. alK- B1K2 2 .
45
Comparison of equations (4.2) and (4.5),
(4. 6) alK-BlK2 :;; a K- B1K2 1 -2- I
indicates that a ski area serving just one group of
homogeneous skiers would maximize revenue by using a lift-
ticket pricing scheme because its revenue exceeds ride ticket
revenue by B1K
2/2. Notice that if the demand function is
perfectly elastic, B1 is equal to zero and both ride and lift
ticketing revenues would be equal. Hence the Barra and Romer
assumption of competitive pricing is a special case.
The revenue generating capabilities of ride-ticketing and
lift-ticketing for a ski area serving a single homogeneous
group are shown diagrammatically in Figure (3). If the lift
capacity is K0 the total revenue under a ride ticket policy is
equal to OP0bqb, since qb ride tickets would be purchased at
price per ticket of P0 • With lift-ticketing, revenue equals
Oabqb. Since, at a capacity of K0 the ski area would be
operating at full capacity with either pricing method, each
skier would receive the same K0/N rides with either ride
ticketing or lift-ticketing. The effective price per ride,
however, is larger with lift-ticketing because each individual
is forced to pay a greater amount for the same number of
rides. Clearly lift-ticketing revenue exceeds ride-ticketing
revenue by P0ab.
The figure illustrates another revenue generating
advantage that lift-ticketing has over ride-ticketing. If the
C1)
u
't:
a.
)
I I
46
Ko K1 K2
a
Po
p1
o~--------~~--~--------~~--------~
Number of Rides
Figure 3. Ride-Ticket versus Lift-Ticket Revenue
01
47
capacity is increased to K1 , ride ticket revenue would only
rise to OP1cqc. The ski area would sell only qc rides because
marginal revenue would be negative at full capacity. With a
capacity of K1 , however, a lift-ticketing scheme would still
generate positive marginal revenue at full capacity with total
lift ticket revenue equal to Oad~. At this capacity the
number of rides sold with lift-ticketing would exceed those
sold with ride-ticketing. Only if the ski area has a capacity
greater than K2 will it operate below full capacity with
either scheme. At capacities greater than K2 , note that qe
rides would be taken. This is exactly twice the qc rides and
twice the revenue which would maximize revenue under ride
ticketing. Accordingly, lift-ticketing provides an incentive
for a ski area to operate at a greater capacity.
Now consider the pricing options for a ski area facing
not only the N1 skiers in group 1 but also a second different
group of N2 skiers and assume that these two separable groups
have different demand elasticities. The demand equation for
group 1 remains as previously described in equation (4.1),
while the demand equation for group 2 is
(4.7) P2 = a2- B202
There are two possible relationships for the two demand
functions. If .the two groups are classified as either "avid"
or "less avid 11 skiers, as described by Barra and Romer,
individuals in group 1, avid skiers, demand a greater number
of rides at all prices than skiers in group 2. such non-
48
intersecting group demand functions are not very interesting
because under such cases the ski area would maximize revenue
by serving just the avid group.
The demand relationship which create a more complex
pricing option is the case where the demand curves are
intersecting, a possibility not considered by Barro and Romer.
One group may have a higher willingness to pay for the first
few rides but a smaller, marginal, willingness to pay for a
large number of rides. What makes this case important is that
with intersecting demand functions ride-ticketing may be the
preferred option. Since lift-ticketing operates subject to the
constraint that all skiers receive the same number of rides,
while ride ticketing allows maximization with adjustments in
ride allocation and price, ride-ticketing revenue may be
greater than lift-ticketing revenue.
A ski area would choose to serve both groups only if it
increased revenue. Assume, for now, that it does maximize ride
ticket revenue by serving the two groups of demanders with a
simple monopolistic pricing scheme and that the capacity
constraint is binding. To analyze the revenue generation under
a ride-ticketing scheme, serving both groups with a single
ride ticket price, it is necessary to sum the two demand
curves horizontally to derive the total market demand curve,
(4. 8} P - a1B2 + a2Bl
Bl+B2
B1B2 K.
Bl+B2
49
The total ride ticket revenue received by serving both groups
is the sum of the ride ticket price, P, and number of rides,
K,
(4.9) TR - a1B2+a B 2 1 B +B K-
1 2
B1B2 K2
B1+B2
To determine whether ride-ticket pricing can exceed lift
ticket pricing under these conditions, compare equations (4.5)
and ( 4. 9) ,
(4.10) a1K- B1K2
2
<
> a1B2+a2B1 K
B1+B2
B1B2 K2
B1+B2
If the left side of equation (4.10) is always greater than the
right side, the revenue derived from serving both groups with
a single ride ticket price can never exceed the revenue
received from serving just group 1 with lift-ticket pricing.
To see this, multiply equation (4.10) by (B1+B2);
2
K 2 < K2 B1B2 > a B K+a B1K-B1B2 -- 1 2 2 2
(4.11) a1B1K+a1B2K-
B12K2
Subtracting a 1B2K from both sides and then dividing by B1
yields,
(4.12) BK
2 < BK2
aK--1- > aK- - 2
1 2 - 2 2
50
Equation 4. 12 indicates that the comparison between ride
ticket and lift-ticket pricing reduces to a simple comparison
of lift-ticket pricing between the two groups. As long as the
total lift-ticket revenue received from serving just group 1
exceeds the total lift-ticket revenue that would be generated
from serving just group 2, lift-ticket pricing revenue exceeds
ride ticket pricing revenue. Otherwise, the ski area would
choose to serve just group 2 with lift tickets rather than
just group 1. This reversal would still generate the result
that lift-ticketing revenue is greater than ride-tick;eting
revenue with a single price per ride.
Of course, the ski area also has the option of serving
both groups with singular priced lift tickets. A revenue
maximizing ski area would choose to serve both groups with a
singular priced lift ticket when such a policy would generate
more revenue than a scheme of serving just one group. In this
case, lift-ticketing would clearly beat simple monopolistic
ride-ticketing. The analysis shows that when facing two groups
with linear demands, simple lift-ticket pricing revenue
exceeds simple monopolistic ride-ticket pricing.
The above result, however, holds only as long as the
assumption of linear demands is valid. Once this assumption is
relaxed to allow for non-linear demands, the results can
change. The simple illustration in Figure (4) shows that a ski
area with a capacity of 30 rides could generate revenues of
$60.00 by serving both skiers with a price per ride of $2.00.
.,
<.0' c:
ro
~
z 0
:::::1 I
c :::::1
CD
jl) '""I
0 CD
3 jl)
:::::1
a. (/)
z c
3
g - "'' 0
0
-
z c
3 C"
~
0
0
Price
Price
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
·
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I a
:c
c.: ...&.